sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Geof Mortlock argues that independent professionals should be brought in to undertake a comprehensive assessment of the Reserve Bank proposals, plus alternative options

Geof Mortlock argues that independent professionals should be brought in to undertake a comprehensive assessment of the Reserve Bank proposals, plus alternative options

By Geof Mortlock*

In December 2018, the Reserve Bank released proposals to increase the Tier 1 capital required of systemically important banks to 16% of risk weighted assets, with 6% of this a regulatory minimum and the remaining 10% a prudential capital buffer.  Under the Reserve Bank’s proposals, the capital requirements for all banks will be much higher than in any comparable country, including Australia, Canada and much of the OECD.

As the Reserve Bank acknowledges, its own stress tests of banks (including stress tests done jointly with the International Monetary Fund (IMF) in 2017) reveal that the banking system is currently resilient to very high shocks to the economy; no bank comes even close to failure under any of the stress testing scenarios applied by the Reserve Bank or IMF.  Regardless of this, the Reserve Bank is proposing extraordinarily high capital ratios for the banks – ostensibly to achieve a ‘1 in 200 year’ resilience to economic shocks.  The aim is to reduce the probability of bank failure to a very low level and thereby reduce the risk of taxpayer costs in any rescue of a bank and to minimise adverse impacts of bank failure on the economy and society.

Implications of the proposals

The Reserve Bank’s proposals will have major implications for the banks and the New Zealand economy.  All else being equal, an increase in capital will lower the probability of bank failure (unless, of course, banks counter this by taking a higher risk appetite to maintain their return on equity – which is a possibility in some cases).  However, as every economist knows, there is no such thing as a free lunch.  The increase in capital requirements, while potentially achieving a lower probability of bank failure, will almost certainly have adverse impacts on the economy by increasing the cost of borrowing and probably reducing the availability of credit.  Some banks (or their parent banks) might decide to reduce their balance sheets or at least slow the rate of growth in assets, rather than put more capital into the banks.  For example, it would not surprise me to see the Australian parent banks take this approach.

The impact of higher capital requirements is likely to be felt mostly by those who can least afford to bear the cost – i.e. those on low to middle incomes borrowing to buy a house or for other household consumption purposes, and small to medium-sized businesses.  They will be faced with higher borrowing costs and/or reduced capacity to borrow.  The increase in capital requirements also makes it less attractive for foreign banks to establish and expand a presence in New Zealand, thereby reducing the contestability, competitiveness and efficiency of the banking system, to the detriment of all of us.

Cost/benefit assessment

One would think that these costs and other adverse impacts would have received a great deal of attention by the Reserve Bank in undertaking a cost/benefit assessment of the proposals.  But no.  By their own admission, they have not yet undertaken a comprehensive cost/benefit analysis.  (Perhaps Adrian Orr was too busy engaging in god-to-god dialogue with Tane Mahuta and the forest fairies to give serious policy matters his attention! Deities are so busy of course.)

In a further paper released by the Reserve Bank on 3 April, providing more information on the capital proposals, the Bank acknowledged this by noting that the additional information released is not a cost/benefit assessment.  And indeed it is not.  The additional information is helpful in providing context for the Reserve Bank’s proposals, but is mainly confined to theoretical assessments of elements underlying the proposals, rather than enabling any meaningful assessment of costs and benefits to be made.

The additional information released recently the Bank does not adequately address most of the key issues at stake.  For example:

  • There is no analysis of ‘reverse stress tests’ of the banking system – i.e. assessing the magnitude of economic shock needed to cause any of the systemic banks to fail and then assessing the probability of such a magnitude of shock occurring.  This should have been done as part of the calibration of the proposed capital requirement.  My hunch is that, if the Reserve Bank conducted reverse stress tests to assess the point of failure for the banks on current capital levels, it would reveal that the level of shock required would be extremely high – much, much higher than New Zealand has ever experienced.  It would be interesting to see this analysis and an assessment of the probability of such a severity of shock occurring, based on global experience.
  • The Reserve Bank’s material contains no analysis of alternative ways of achieving the objective of a very low probability of bank failure, such as strengthening the requirements in relation to bank governance, risk management, risk appetite, risk culture and exposure concentration.  Instead, the Reserve Bank focuses solely on increasing the capital requirement.  In contrast, in other OECD countries, there is a much more balanced approach to achieving a low probability of bank failure that includes not just capital, but also requirements in relation to bank governance, risk management, quality of lending and exposure concentration.  The unbalanced approach by the Reserve Bank is out of step with the rest of the world.  It makes no sense.  And I suspect that it will prove to be a costly mistake for New Zealand.
  • The Reserve Bank’s material contains no analysis of alternative loss absorption mechanisms.  Its focus is on Tier 1 capital (essentially share capital).  In contrast, other countries have assessed and some are implementing alternative loss-absorbing mechanisms to enable banks to be resolved without taxpayer costs or damage to the financial system, including establishing tranches of contractual bail-in debt issued into wholesale markets.  Indeed, globally systemically important banks are now required to have this form of loss absorption.  Yet no serious analysis of this has been published by the Reserve Bank.
  • There is no analysis of the means by which banks can restore themselves to financial soundness following an impairment to capital or liquidity, such as through recovery planning.  In almost all OECD countries, supervisory agencies have established recovery planning requirements for banks.  This has been one of the key responses to the global financial crisis and is designed to enable banks to re-establish capital and liquidity buffers following a severe financial shock.  In New Zealand, the Reserve Bank has done nothing at all in this area, in contrast to the very substantial progress made in recovery planning requirements in Australia, UK, EU, US and much of Asia.
  • There is no analysis of the resolution options that can be used to resolve a failing bank in ways that minimise the adverse impact on the banking system and economy, while minimising taxpayer costs.  If reliable mechanisms can be used to manage bank failures in ways that greatly reduce their systemic impact, this reduces the need for very high up-front capital requirements.  Yet all the Reserve Bank has done in this space is to implement the requirements for its so-called ‘Open Bank Resolution’ (OBR) form of resolving a failing bank.  This policy is half-baked at best.  It is actually dangerous because, if OBR were implemented without deposit insurance (and the Reserve Bank has consistently opposed deposit insurance), then it would likely trigger a mass depositor run on the banking system.  It is also a failed policy on other grounds because it relies on government guarantees being applied to the post-haircut liabilities of the bank in question.  In all likelihood, if any Minister of Finance were stupid enough to implement OBR, it would require a blanket guarantee of all banks’ liabilities for a considerable period after the implementation.  The bizarre outcome might be to actually worsen taxpayer risk and increase moral hazard.  OBR was a useful mind experiment when we (including me, as one of its early creators) came up with the concept many years ago.  But no serious, intelligent resolution authority/central bank would be daft enough to implement it in the form conceived by the Reserve Bank.  But then again, no central bank on the planet promotes itself as a god of the financial forest. Only in New Zealand!

Hopefully, some adult thinking will emerge in the Reserve Bank to develop realistic resolution policies that minimise government liability and risk to the financial system.  One such avenue is a joint resolution arrangement with the Australian authorities in the form of a properly structured contractual bail-in debt arrangement that keeps the New Zealand subsidiaries as part of the global parent banking groups.  This would be much lower cost for New Zealand than the Reserve Bank’s oddly conceived plan to separate the subsidiaries from the parent banks in a resolution.  Australia has been open to such an idea.  The Reserve Bank has not.  I hope that the Minister of Finance will knock some heads together to make progress in the direction of some serious joint Australia-New Zealand resolution option.

  • The Reserve Bank has also failed to provide any analysis of whether the capital proposals will result in significant financial sector activity moving from the regulated part of the financial sector (i.e. the banks) to unregulated non-bank lenders, to the detriment of the efficiency and possibly the stability of the financial system and the economy.

The Reserve Bank notes that it will carry out a cost-benefit assessment for a Regulatory Impact Statement to help inform and describe final decisions in the review.  This is an extraordinary statement by the Reserve Bank.  It has released proposals for a very large increase in capital requirements that will have considerable impacts on the economy and financial system, but has not yet undertaken or published a cost/benefit analysis.  When the Bank does – finally – get around to undertaking such an analysis, this will only be once the final decisions have been made.  What is the use of that?  A meaningful cost/benefit analysis should occur at an early stage in policy formulation.  It should have accompanied the release of the capital proposals in December.  It should inform the discussions.  It should have been undertaken for a number of policy options so that different options could be meaningfully assessed in terms of their respective benefits and costs.

Instead, the Reserve Bank will undertake its cost/benefit assessment only once it has finalised its decisions.  How objective will this analysis be, you ask?  It does not take much cynicism to reach the correct conclusion on that.  The cost/benefit analysis that the Reserve Bank finally releases will be formulated to justify its proposal.  It will not be objective.  It will not be rigorous.  It will likely not be vetted by an independent party.  And it will probably not be accompanied by cost/benefit analyses of alternative policy options.

Sadly, this is the standard we have come to expect of the Reserve Bank and of many government agencies.  Cost/benefit analyses for regulatory proposals in New Zealand are typically only done once the agency in question has already made up its mind on the policy to be pursued.  They are rarely released at an early stage in the consultation process so as to inform the scrutiny of the proposal and competing options.  They are typically engineered to justify the proposal selected.  They are poorly developed.  And they are subject to inadequate independent scrutiny.  Some government agencies do a better job of this than others in preparing cost/benefit assessments.  The Reserve Bank has a poor track record in this regard.  And that is because it operates as a power unto itself, sheltered by an excessive degree of operational autonomy and lacking in any meaningful external scrutiny.

In other countries – including Australia – regulatory proposals are typically required to be released at a much earlier stage in the consultation process and are subject to rigorous external scrutiny.  In Australia, this is done by the Office of Best Practice Regulation (OBPR) - a senior-level government agency that has real teeth and resources, and can reject policy proposals which do not pass scrutiny by them.  In New Zealand there is no equivalent.  Treasury reviews cost/benefit analyses, but lacks the resources to do the job well.  It has none of the powers that the Australian OBPR has.

So, what we have from the Reserve Bank is a capital proposal that is not backed by robust analysis and is not accompanied by alternative policy options to assess the best policy/policies to achieve the desired objective of a resilient banking system at low economic and efficiency costs.  In short, the Reserve Bank has developed a simplistic policy to substantially increase bank capital requirements instead of exploring a much more sensible, balanced array of policies that could achieve the same outcome at much lower cost.  Moreover, it has failed to undertake any meaningful cost/benefit analysis of its proposals, including the potentially very significant adverse impact on longer term economic growth.  This is not good enough.

Independent review of the capital proposals

What is needed is an in-depth independent, professional assessment of the Reserve Bank’s capital proposals.  Treasury will no doubt review the Reserve Bank’s cost/benefit assessment once the Regulatory Impact Statement has been prepared.  However, that is too late in the policy formulation stage.  Moreover, with all due respect to Treasury, it lacks the depth of knowledge needed for a rigorous assessment of the different policy options and the costs and benefits of each.  What is needed is for Treasury, at the direction of Grant Robertson, to engage a couple of independent professionals (such as an academic specialised in bank regulation and a recently retired foreign senior bank regulator – e.g. John Laker, former Chairman of APRA) to undertake a comprehensive assessment of the Reserve Bank proposals, plus alternative options.  The findings of this assessment should be incorporated into the Treasury’s own review and the results be made public.  The independent review would considerably assist the quality of the process of assessing the Reserve Bank’s proposals and may assist in reaching a more sensible outcome.

An independent review would sensibly include consideration of:

  • the magnitude of economic shock needed to cause any of the large banks in New Zealand to fail, and the probability of such a shock occurring;
  • the level of capital needed to enable banks to survive a plausible range of severe economic shocks;
  • the composition of capital requirements and other loss absorption facilities that would be suitable to enable banks to survive severe economic shocks, including whether (as in many countries) a substantial proportion could be in the form of debt instruments that convert to equity upon defined breaches of core equity capital ratios;
  • the impact of the proposed increase in capital ratios on bank lending, interest rates, property prices and economic growth (with implications for government revenue);
  • the impact of the proposed increase in capital ratios on banking system contestability, competitiveness and financial inclusion (especially for those on low incomes);
  • the alternative policy options for strengthening the resilience of the banking system, including strengthening Reserve Bank supervision of banks’ governance, risk management practices, lending policies, and recovery planning;
  • the bank failure resolution options that could be applied to maintain financial stability with minimal taxpayer risk (and hence reduce the need for high capital ratios).

The Minister of Finance and Treasury need to give serious attention to these matters.  And the sooner the better.


*Geof Mortlock is a Wellington-based international financial consultant who undertakes regular consulting work for the International Monetary Fund, World Bank, Toronto Centre and may other organisations.  He draws on a long career in bank regulation and financial stability/central banking, including years at a senior level in the Reserve Bank of New Zealand and Australian Prudential Regulation Authority.  He has participated in senior-level committees of the Financial Stability Board and Basel Committee in Switzerland.  See www.mortlock.co.nz

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

16 Comments

How much can they actually pass the costs back onto taxpayers? Would not our challenger banks (who already have higher capital ratios) just undercut and force the big banks to follow and squeeze margin?

Up
0

When a bank fails no one will attach much weight to anything supporting low bank capital.

Would you lend money to a business with only 16% (or currently less) of their own money invested in it? Would you lend money to a business with 6+ times leverage and only receive 0.1% pa in return for the risk that would be taking on? A lot of people do apparently. For any other business this would be considered irresponsible, so why not look at banks from a more realistic perspective.

With respect to scare tactics about a bank run if the OBR is implemented it will be done over a weekend and deposits will be severely limited to a daily amount. The outflow of money would be a relative trickle. This is now a standard strategy since Cyprus and Greece.

I think a better strategy is to bail out depositors, transfer the loan book to another bank for $10, and leave the remains of the bank to suffer its fate at the hands of capitalism.

Up
0

Given that I can insure my house, my car, my health, and land via the EQC, the ability to insure bank deposits should exist.

The issue is simply what is the most efficient way of achieving this.

I agree with the article that a number of options should be explored.

There is also the issue of, if higher capital levels are required for the major banks, then why not every lender? Everyone should have the opportunity to safeguard their savings (at a cost).

One alternative to look at is:

1) make government bonds & treasuries across all time periods freely available at the retail level through commercial banks. These represent the risk free rate of return. The commercial banks would clip, say 0.01% as admin fee.

2) Regulate to make the banks & other lenders get their own deposit insurance. They could then manage their own capital levels in response (still above an international benchmark to provide some cover for corruption/false reporting etc)

3) The deposit insurance would be reflected in the % rates offered (would be lower to cover the insurance cost) and the maximum insured deposit with that institution.

Up
0

Wow. Very thorough indeed. There has to be an easy way through here, surely. We're only this big, our markets & our expertise only go so deep. And following the Australians might be fine for some, but they don't know everything. I can see Mr Orr's proposal might be a bit simplistic on the surface, but if it encourages the sort of discussion as above then that's good right? I take your point on the depth & breadth of our public services, or lack thereof, but hey, that's NZ Inc across the board isn't it?

Up
0

"There is no analysis of ‘reverse stress tests’ of the banking system – i.e. assessing the magnitude of economic shock needed to cause any of the systemic banks to fail and then assessing the probability of such a magnitude of shock occurring."

They've run the numbers, that is why they're doing this. It's not random that they've gone for massive balls to the wall requirements. But they won't say why, because people would freak out.

Up
0

There are a number of well-informed and respected independent commentators calling out the RBNZ's behaviour on this. It's not so much the 16% (which cannot be justified in my opinion), but how they got there. The analysis I've seen is so light it wouldn't pass muster in a Masters thesis, let alone one of the most significant changes to banking regulation seen in NZ. None of us should be comfortable with it, regardless of what side of the fence you sit on house prices.

Up
0

When you have bail-in legislation and the risk of deposits being used to shore up bank capital (as passed by the previous administration) but at the same time no government depositor guarantee to protect depositors in the event of a failure then yes additional capital requirements are essential and when you’ve had a decade of credit creation by banks - akin to drunken sailors throwing money around the port’s pubs. Then yes higher capital ratios are somewhat essential. The other issue is the risks the recklessness of the parents (Aussie banks) have created.

Up
0

Some compelling evidence in support of Adrian Orr's proposal… (see journal ref below)

The two variables that provided the highest forecasting accuracy (98.25%) are: (1) Tier 1 (core) risk-based capital over total assets (T1CRC), and (2) total interest expense over total interest income (TIE).......

...We collected data for all failed U.S. banks from 2007 to 2013. Our dataset includes all types of banking institutions, such as commercial banks, savings associations and national banks....... Our final dataset includes 481 failed and 962 solvent banks, giving a total of 1443. For each bank, four observations of 36 variables and financial ratios were collected from their financial statements over a period of four years.....

Forecasting bank failures and stress testing: A machine
learning approach.
International Journal of Forecasting 34(2018) 440-445 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijforecast.2018.01.009

Up
0

Geoff Mortlock's assertions are in line with Ian Harrison's paper 'the 30 billion dollar whim' and with Michael Reddell's blog post.

All three point to the same thing - that the cost/benefit is essentially unknown and that far from being a prior input into the consideration of options, it seems destined to be an ex-post-facto justification of the eventual decision.

And then there's Eric Crampton's demolition of the Treasury's latest excursion into the nether realms of Magical Thinking, at (paywalled) NBR....plus a delicious take on the whole batty sequence - Our Tarot Treasury.

The old saying springs to mind - with friends like these, who needs enemies?

Up
0

Mr Mortlock wants an "independent review" So it's bound to happen. This government never misses an opportunity for a working group.

Up
0

Seemed to miss it in relation to the oil and gas ban.

Up
0

There most definitely will not be a review. Dollars to donuts Labour have been briefed and approve - Orr is the next Labour Finance/Shadow Finance Minister after all. The amount of "well-being" language gives it away.

Up
0

Re: cost benefit analysis; The cost would be borne by the banks as reduced profits, but the benefit would accrue to society as a stable banking system, with a lower government debt interest rate.

Re: Independent review; Who would be appointed? Banking insiders?

Re: Cost to society; I doubt banks would stop lending altogether. Maybe they’d increase their derivative exposure so we should really be having an “Independent review” on whether to have Glass-Steagall type legislation to separate commercial and investment banking.

Up
0

What investment banking? None of the Australian Banks (excluding Macquarie) have investment banking divisions, no equity capital markets, no equity under-writing, some investment grade DCM sure but they underwrite none of it. Their derivatives exposure largely nets and is almost exclusively vanilla swaps. Their risk-taking as measured by Var is a rounding error on Group results (diversified var averages around $10m across the four, trivial)

Up
0

So you're saying that a failure in the 700 trillion dollar global derivatives market, with all the contagion effects, would have no impact on the balance sheet of NZ or Australian banks? Australia is currently having a senate inquiry into the separation of the banks. https://www.aph.gov.au/Parliamentary_Business/Committees/Senate/Economi…

Up
0

Are you serious? This Bill is sponsored by Pauline Hanson and isn't worth the paper it is written on. 90% of Australian bank derivatives are interest rate swaps, they have never been safer and will never be a systemic risk. The bulk of them is inter-bank and they are collateralised.

Up
0