sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Independent economist Brian Easton says public policy towards tobacco consumption remains politically sensitive

Public Policy / opinion
Independent economist Brian Easton says public policy towards tobacco consumption remains politically sensitive
cigaretterf1.jpg
Source: 123rf.com

This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.


In 1983, a young researcher was told by a medium-level Treasury official that Treasury policy was to abandon excise duties on tobacco. The senior Treasury economist that I consulted, famed for his commonsense, snorted ‘we need the money’. He explained that no-excise-duty was the ambition of a couple of very ideological Treasury officials – later we would call them ‘Rogernomes’ or ‘neoliberals’ – who objected to state intervention.

I recount this incident to remind you that tobacco policy has an ideological dimension as well as being affected by lobbying from the commercial tobacco interests, which are not particularly ideological but pursue their self-interest. A ‘Socialists for Ciggies’ lobby would be generously funded too. (One may suspect the funding of favourable lobby groups tobacco interests is because they do not want New Zealand successes to set an international example.)

Understanding the ideological dimension explains why some not very impressive arguments are trotted out to justify reducing tobacco excise. It is common for an ideological justification to be clothed in practical garb. Understanding the commercial lobbying explains why alcohol excise is not also under review. The liquor interests cannot be spending enough on the right-wing lobby groups.

Tobacco excise duties are still Treasury policy; it still needs the money. But there is a sound economic justification for excise duties on tobacco. Smoking damages smokers’ health, compromising heart and lungs and triggering cancers. The tobacco excise contributes to the cost of health service treatments. (The revenue actually exceeds annual costs. However, if everyone stopped smoking tomorrow, they would experience some health gains immediately, but would still have higher treatment costs for some decades. So the duty is covering future costs, just as taxing carbon emissions is intended to offset global warming which lasts centuries.)

The priority of revenue collecting is demonstrated by the fact that currently the level of excise duty is indexed to general consumer prices. As prices rise, so does the tax (although there are some in the current government who would like to end this practice). The indexation arose because it was such a hassle for Treasury to get the Minister of Finance to raise the excise rate; now it is automatic. The small incremental changes probably don’t have a lot of effect on smoking, whereas holding off the increases and then having a big increase encourages more smokers to give up.

Another economic dimension has been the smoke-free legislation. Once smokers had the right to pollute others’ airspace, which many non-smokers found offensive. The realisation that passive smokers could also suffer health damage led to a law change which removed the right for a smoker to infringe the airspace of others. The health damage from passive smoking is quite small compared to that from active smoking, but it provided the political lever to introduce the smoke-free legislation.

Over the years the amount of smoking has decreased. In 2011 the government set a target of only 5 percent of smokers in the population by 2025. That seemed ambitious at the time but it looks as though the target will be attained.

The big difference may be the introduction of vaping which enables the tobacco addict to switch access to a nicotine source which appears to be less harmful, because there is less poison in the inhaling. We cannot be sure how less harmful it is. It took decades to track how much tobacco damaged health and we have insufficient data to be sure of vaping’s long-run effects. (The medical advice is that addicted smokers should switch to vaping, but non-smokers should not take it up.)

The neoliberal’s ideological case is that they object to the state interfering in individual lives, especially when it tries to change behaviour. If people want to smoke, they are entitled to make that decision without state interference. I am not unsympathetic to that general principle, especially if the smokers are paying for their health (and other social) costs and they are not infringing others’ airspace.

The economics discipline is framed by the importance of individual choice. But how addiction fits into the economists’ approach is unclear. Most smokers are addicted to nicotine; many wish they could give up smoking, but they can’t. It is easy to say ‘don’t get addicted’ but it happens with other things we consume. (Kate Shepherd famously remarked that ladies of her time were addicted to cups of tea.)

The economics approach to personal decision making began before psychology as a science was founded. Behavioural economics draws upon modern psychology, but I have yet to see how it incorporates addiction. (Some of the neoliberal arguments are just plain silly. A famous one was that being unable to give up an addiction was akin to saying you wanted to get married but could not find anyone to marry.)

I am uneasy that the (handful of) tobacco companies profit from getting people addicted to their product despite it being harmful. That position is not based on deep economic theory but on the commonsense of a senior Treasury official. In particular it suggests we should target behaviour which results in addiction.

We are not going to stop teenagers trying out a fag, especially if their elders say ‘don’t’. Daily smoking is already low among teenagers, Hopefully they will completely stop by their early twenties. That should be an aim of public policy.

This approach suggests we should not get too agitated about the (diminishing proportion of) older adult smokers. They are paying for the costs of their health care (although sometimes, say for heart conditions, they will not be treated unless they give up smoking because the treatment is not very effective). They are not polluting our airspace. We may be sorry for them; we should give them as much assistance to give up smoking as we can. But they know the risks.

I expect the previous paragraph will cause outrage among some of my colleagues in the health profession. Theirs is a different ideology committed to saving every life they can. Their view is smokers are killing themselves; they should not. It is an approach I respect – it involves a commitment to preserving life well beyond what the advocates are paid. But we all do risky things, like skydiving and jay walking, aware there are dangers.

Indeed, we may be facing a dispute within the anti-tobacco lobby about what to do once the target of 5% smokers is attained. One side will want to reduce the target further; the other will be more relaxed about adult smokers, focusing the effort on limiting adolescent smoking. Meanwhile the neoliberal lobby, backed by the commercial tobacco interests, seems to be in office and perhaps in power. We may be facing a major political wrangle, but a three-sided one.


*Brian Easton, an independent scholar, is an economist, social statistician, public policy analyst and historian. He was the Listener economic columnist from 1978 to 2014. This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

15 Comments

" especially if the smokers are paying for their health (and other social) costs and they are not infringing others’ airspace"

But therein lies the rub. If smokers were to be denied public healthcare, then who's next? The obvious candidates would those deemed to be too overweight. Who would make the decisions? Once on that slippery slope, where would it end? 

Having said that, as our health costs rise inexorably along with our population of older citizens, then some form of rationing might be necessary. Tough questions, tough choices.

Up
0

re ... "If smokers were to be denied public healthcare, then who's next? The obvious candidates would those deemed to be too overweight."

reductio ad absurdum? Sure gets close. It is a strawman.

re ... "then some form of rationing might be necessary."

Rationing is already done in the health systems in almost all countries. (Even the USA.)

Up
2

Smokers are already denied healthcare....as are the elderly. We have had a (unspoken) public health triage system for years.

Anyone who disputes such is living in a large river in Egypt.

Up
0

You'll find that with many obese individuals in need of orthopedic surgery, the surgeons aren't willing to operate on them unless they can show a dedication to losing weight so to ensure they are taking the implications of the surgery seriously and don't wind up needing revision surgery in a short amount of time e.g spinal surgeries for disc prolapses. Add in smoking and surgeons are even less likely to operate as smoking reduces the bodies ability to heal and also comes with other risks with bones such as fractured bone turning necrotic and needing more extensive and expensive surgery to remedy. Thsi isn't so much discrimination as it is risk to the individual themselves as well as the healthcare system.

Up
1

We are not going to stop teenagers trying out a fag, especially if their elders say ‘don’t’. Daily smoking is already low among teenagers, Hopefully they will completely stop by their early twenties. That should be an aim of public policy.

Taken to the logical extreme, the aim of public policy should be to remove the products from the market altogether.  But given the products have been legal for so long, we have a population of addicts who (perhaps) should not be denied the right to keep feeding their addiction to the harmful product. 

Therefore, the next most logical action is to prevent the growing of new addicts - and hence the (now cancelled) policy of raising the age of purchase one year every year.

The government that cancelled THAT regulatory initiative should have to explain why they did that.  And yes, the only reason can be to continue to collect excise tax ad infinitum forever.  Such cynicism is hard to believe. 

Up
4

I just hope cigarettes will be free if WW3 kicks off .... not much point in worrying about everyones health if that day comes....

Up
0

Ban something and the gangs and crooks will profit....it's quite simple, but something many just can't quite get their head around. 

Look no further than Prohibition in the USA...

Cigarette smuggling is already big business. 

Up
0

Would that be worse than the status quo however? For a lot of other drugs it has been decided that the downsides of the black market are outweighed by the health and safety effects of the drug.

Most people who smoke and do not give up will die from it, and it is highly addictive so many smokers find it impossible to quit. There is not many other products you can buy off the shelf like that.

Up
1

Prohibition resulted in thousands of murders and incidents like the St. Valentines Day Massacre. You want that here? Smoking is voluntary. If I was a smoker I suppose I could always grow the stuff myself. And maybe sell it. 

Everyone knows the risks, it's nothing new. That smoking causes deadly diseases has been known for eons.

I'm not sure why anyone would be worried about smokers when the country's in the grip of a drug epidemic. 

Up
0

Or, as the logic goes with cannabis to counter the black market make it legal to grow-your-own and manufacture products under license (just as the current corporate tobacco monopolies do).

I think I read somewhere that the chemicals added to commercial tobacco to keep it 'continuously' burning contribute to the addictiveness.  My guess is a 'home grown' loose tobacco product would/could be sold without these chemical additives.

 

Up
1

The continuously burning requirement is from smokers themselves rather than from the tobacco companies. It is managed mainly through the drying and curing process. One of areas of tobacco production that makes it so difficult. Once done to exactly the right measure, the tobacco is sealed to ensure it maintains the right levels of moisture (water and oils) and burns continuously. Most (all?) of the reports of harmful additives for this purpose are urban myths.

Up
1

re ... "Look no further than Prohibition in the USA..."

Funny you say that.

Some friends and I were discussing this and one pointed out that the production of alcohol and tobacco are chalk and cheese. He surfaced an excellent economics paper done by a masters student. In a nutshell, alcohol can be produced just about anywhere by anyone and done very discretely so its production is difficult to police. Tobacco on the other hand requires significant chunks of land to be produced at any economic scale unless prices are extremely high, and while planted for months they are easy to both see and smell.

But yes. Criminals will supply some tobacco. But very little. It's extremely bulky (and smelly). Because it is consumed in high amounts and the bulk is so large, no substantial quantities will enter NZ without interception.

Edited: To those who replied but didn't read the sentence above, "Criminals will supply some tobacco."....

So how much tobacco is consumed in Australia? Roughly 12,000 tonnes. And the illicit tobacco is roughly 2,200 tonnes. Australia's border is much more porous than NZ's so that's not too surprising. Some years ago, Australia didn't really have a handle on how much tobacco entered illegally and escaped duty. Thanks to the tobacco companies (see link), the Aus government decided there was a good payback to policing illegal imports and they ramped up policing. Smuggling is a game to many. Has been for centuries. It'll continue.

Source: https://treasury.gov.au/sites/default/files/2022-03/258735_british_amer…

Up
1

Haven't you read in the papers and on the internet about the huge amounts of cigarettes being intercepted on the way to NZ?

It's a very profitable business.

https://www.trademe.co.nz/a/marketplace/home-living/outdoor-garden-cons…

Up
0

Do you live under a rock?  Its a $4 billion black  market in Australia.  Everyone in Australia knows where to go to buy illegal cigarettes and vapes.

https://www.news.com.au/finance/business/retail/ruthless-illegal-cigare…

 

Up
0

I think if you honestly seek answers to the following questions, then you'll probably conclude that NZ’s tobacco policy has been a failure. 

1. Smoking rates among youth have declined in NZ over the last few decades, but they’ve also declined sharply in Germany where tobacco is 1/10 of the cost compared to NZ.  In that context, to what degree has NZ’s extremely high tobacco tax really reduced tobacco consumption?

2. It appears that smoking is particularly prevalent among lower socioeconomic classes.  To what degree has NZ’s tobacco tax policy exacerbated general inequality and increased the wealth gap in NZ?

3. What is the exact percentage of families who’re heavily reliant on state support, and whose family members are also spending money on tobacco?

4. It’s a truism that taxes incentivise certain types of economic activity.  How has NZ’s 2 billion dollar a year tobacco tax policy manifested into business activity over the last decade?  Could those economic incentives have been better directed (towards productivity, for example)?

Up
0