sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Labour's monetary policy employment target met by questions on how to measure success (NAIRU?) and whether people will continue to trust the Reserve Bank. Time Inconsistency anyone?

Labour's monetary policy employment target met by questions on how to measure success (NAIRU?) and whether people will continue to trust the Reserve Bank. Time Inconsistency anyone?

By Alex Tarrant

Grant Robertson was immediately confronted with the inevitable question regarding Labour’s new stance that monetary policy should target full employment at his great unveiling on Monday: how do you measure whether the Reserve Bank has hit that target?

Robertson has been clear that Labour would not look to set a numerical employment or unemployment figure or range like the Bank already has for its price stability mandate (annual CPI inflation between 1% and 3%).

Add into the mix that different people have different definitions of what the ‘full employment’ or ‘natural rate of unemployment’ in the economy could be (Treasury and the Reserve Bank are currently half a percent apart) and you’ve got the central problem Robertson’s going to face both in explaining the policy to the general electorate ahead of the election, and when/if he’s Finance Minister trying to explain why the unemployment rate has just risen when Labour had just promised the Reserve Bank would help cut it.

In short, how do you avoid the charge that the new wording is merely window dressing designed to make it look like the government’s trying to do something to reduce unemployment by getting the Reserve Bank to help out on a simple economic variable with some complex policy tool that the general public doesn’t really understand?

“I’m not proposing to have a specific [unemployment] rate [target], because in part, full employment will differ depending on different conditions in the economic cycle at different times,” Robertson told a crowd of academics, at least one bond trader and Reserve Bank hierarchy at Victoria University’s business school Monday.

But this wasn’t helped by the fact that one report Monday morning had quoted Robertson saying full employment would “most definitely” be less than 5% in the current climate. On the very morning of the policy announcement, Robertson had already set a range for if future economic conditions while he was Finance Minister were the same as they are today. (And with the election less than six months away – that’s not an unlikely scenario).

Labour’s policy that minutes of a new OCR-setting committee would be published would allow for transparency around whether the Bank has taken employment outcomes into account in its actions setting the Official Cash Rate, Robertson said.

And he was also quick to mention the variability of what full employment might be defined as. In fact, he went as far as to say that inclusion of the term ‘full employment’ in the policy, rather than following the US language of ‘maximum employment’ was due to Labour’s broader policy of ‘full employment’.

NAIRU

But he also ventured one possible variable that Labour might use to keep tabs on how well the Reserve Bank is doing on its newest mandate: measure the unemployment rate against the NAIRU, or the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment.

NAIRU is an idea that sprung up in response to Kiwi economist Bill Philips’ work on the connection (or non-connection depending on how you argue it and over what time frame you look at it) between unemployment and inflation. If you’re in NAIRU you’re not on a Pacific Island. Rather, the inflation rate is not rising or falling. It’s the rate of unemployment at which inflation is stable.

Robertson's actual comment was that NAIRU "could be the starting point for measuring success or failure."

There are two potential meanings to this. The first is if NAIRU is used to signify what 'full employment' is in the economy at any one time. If this is the case, then the full employment mandate for the bank is redundant. All you need is stable inflation, and you've hit the NAIRU.

The second potential meaning is that you're asking the Reserve Bank to try and ensure full employment, even if the corresponding rate comes in below the NAIRU (that's once you've figured out what the NAIRU is - it's more of an idea than a hard-cast variable like the unemployment rate is).

The problem in the second scenario is that if you undershoot the NAIRU then the result is inflation. And inflation could mean raising the Official Cash Rate to restrict economic activity, which then leads to a rising unemployment rate.

Try explaining that during the Election 2020 hustings.

Time inconsistency

But the day's cracker of a question came from Victoria University’s Bob Buckle. He challenged the policy as Labour effectively claiming that the principles of time inconsistency of optimal plans no longer applied. It was these principles that underlay the present Reserve Bank Act.

For those wondering, read this article by economist Richard Dennis published by the San Francisco Federal Reserve, which very helpfully uses the scenario of a central bank faced with an inflation target and a full employment target. It basically relates to the risk that people stop trusting the central bank – ie the first time it created more inflation to get unemployment lower may have worked, but the people won’t be fooled again and will now expect higher inflation, ask for continually higher wages, leading potentially to a wage-price spiral as in the 1970s. 

In other words, the Bank might have an incentive to say one thing about inflation but do something different.

For the record, Robertson said he did not accept Buckle’s premise – Labour would continue with the Reserve Bank’s inflation targeting model, he said. Translation: you can continue to trust that the Bank will keep medium term CPI inflation within the band, despite its new mandate.

Make your own minds up. The San Fran Fed article is from 2003, so I’m sure they won’t mind us reprinting it below. Enjoy.

Over the past 20 years inflation in the U.S. economy has been relatively low, averaging about 2.5%; moreover, it has been relatively stable, with a standard deviation of just 1.0%. These statistics may give the impression that inflation has been tamed, or even beaten into submission. However, the period has not been without inflation scares; consider, for example, the run up in inflation prior to the 1990 recession and the preemptive policy intervention in 1994. Looking back to the 1970s, high inflation was a very real concern. Following the two oil price shocks of the 1970s, inflation ratcheted up, peaking at 10.5% in 1975 and at 9.6% in 1981. While policymakers could not have prevented the oil price shocks from occurring, the fact that monetary policy seemed unable to curtail the ensuing inflation was unsettling. Whether inappropriate monetary policies were pursued in the 1970s is an issue that has received considerable attention in recent years.

While a number of explanations have been put forward to explain the “great inflation” of the 1970s, one of the most influential is the time-inconsistency theory advocated by Kydland and Prescott (1977) and Barro and Gordon (1983). Time-inconsistency describes situations where, with the passing of time, policies that were determined to be optimal yesterday are no longer perceived to be optimal today and are not implemented. The key insight that Kydland and Prescott had was that the reason why these policies would not be implemented also could lead to inflationary policies being implemented in their place. In other words, time-inconsistency could generate higher inflation.

If one accepts that the time-inconsistency story is a good description of what went on in the 1970s (see Ireland, 1999, for an empirical analysis), then the relative absence of inflation since the mid-1980s may suggest that time-inconsistency is not a current problem for policymakers. However, time-inconsistency can affect more than just the average rate of inflation that prevails in the economy. In particular, it can influence how policymakers respond to shocks and how resources are allocated through time. This Economic Letter looks at time-inconsistency, describing why the same mechanisms that can lead to higher average inflation also can hamper policymakers’ efforts to keep inflation stable.

Discretionary inflation bias

To see how Kydland and Prescott (1977) showed that time-inconsistency could lead to excessively high inflation, suppose that the central bank has the twin goals of trying to keep inflation close to some target level and unemployment close to the natural rate, the unemployment rate that would prevail in a world without market imperfections. Now suppose that there are market imperfections, such as monopolistic competition or union behavior, or distortions caused by fiscal policy, so that the unemployment rate that clears the labor market is inefficiently high, lying above the natural rate. To keep unemployment close to the natural rate, the central bank must try to lower unemployment below the inefficiently high rate that ordinarily clears the labor market. In this model, workers negotiate their wage rate with firms based on what they expect inflation to be. To the extent that workers correctly anticipate the inflation rate, the prevailing unemployment rate is the (inefficiently high) market-clearing rate.

As Kydland and Prescott showed, in this model the central bank’s desire to reduce unemployment to the natural rate leads to time-inconsistent behavior. Suppose that the inflation target is 2%; the optimal monetary policy recognizes that workers cannot be systematically fooled and, consequently, that the unemployment rate cannot systematically depart from the market-clearing rate. Despite its twin goals, therefore, the best the central bank can do is announce that it will set monetary policy such that inflation equals 2%, and then follow through on that announcement and let the labor market clear at the market-clearing level.

But this optimal policy is time-inconsistent and will not be implemented. If workers believe the central bank’s policy announcement and negotiate a contract with firms providing for a 2% nominal wage increase, then the central bank’s range of options changes. Instead of following through and implementing the announced policy, the central bank can create a little more inflation–an inflation surprise–which lowers workers’ real wages, stimulating firms’ demand for labor. With the nominal wage rate fixed, the labor market now clears at a lower unemployment rate. Thus, at the cost of slightly higher inflation, the economy reaps the benefit of lower unemployment. Kydland and Prescott showed that, in balancing these costs and benefits, the central bank would find it advantageous to create the inflation surprise and not implement the announced policy.

Of course, workers soon will realize that the central bank’s announcements are not credible, and they will come to expect higher inflation. And when workers expect higher inflation, it becomes increasingly costly for the central bank to create an inflation surprise. The equilibrium outcome is for inflation to rise to the point where the central bank finds that the benefits of any additional inflation surprises are fully offset by their costs. At this inflation rate, the central bank has no incentive to create an inflation surprise. But because there are no inflation surprises, workers fully anticipate the inflation rate, and the labor market does not clear at the natural rate of unemployment: instead the higher market-clearing rate prevails. Sadly, the fact that the central bank can revisit its announced policy after wages are set leaves the economy with inefficiently high inflation, but no reduction in the unemployment rate. The discrepancy between the average inflation rate that occurs and the inflation target is known as the discretionary inflation bias.

Relating the Kydland and Prescott story back to the 1970s, the oil price shocks drove up firms’ production costs and led to rising unemployment, thereby giving policymakers an incentive to create inflation surprises. Through policymakers’ efforts to keep the unemployment rate in check, inflation blossomed; the unemployment rate crept up regardless, particularly following the 1974 oil price shock.

However, the Kydland and Prescott story is more than just a sophisticated way of explaining high inflation; it has other profound consequences. For example, time-inconsistency can affect a government’s ability to issue nominal debt (bonds) or alter the type of asset that a government uses to issue debt. The expected real return on nominal debt depends on the purchaser’s expectation of future inflation. If investors purchase the bonds anticipating a tight monetary policy, and hence lower future inflation, then they will pay a higher price for the bonds than if they expected a loose monetary policy and higher future inflation. But while a central bank may promise a tight monetary policy, once the nominal debt has been issued, the government may pressure the central bank to pursue an expansionary monetary policy in order to inflate away the real value of the government’s nominal liabilities. Anticipating the government’s incentives, investors will demand higher rates of return on government bonds, or they may require that the rate of return on bonds be indexed to inflation outcomes.

Stabilization bias

But time-inconsistency is not just a phenomenon that produces high inflation rates. Indeed, recent literature has focused not on the average inflation rate, nor on the discretionary inflation bias, but instead on how time-inconsistency affects the economy’s transition through time and how it affects policymakers’ ability to stabilize inflation (Dennis and Söderström 2002). Because time-inconsistent policies can alter how the economy evolves over time and how the economy responds to shocks, it is important even in environments where inflation is low.

Consider again a central banker whose objective is to keep inflation close to some target rate and the unemployment rate close to the market-clearing level. Typically, a central banker must trade these two objectives off against each other: a negative supply shock, such as an adverse productivity shock or an oil price shock, raises both unemployment and prices, and moving interest rates to mitigate the movement in either variable has adverse effects on the other. Recognizing this trade-off, when a supply shock occurs, the central banker must take a gradual approach, returning inflation to its target rate over a number of periods, so as not to create unnecessary unemployment. But households’ and firms’ expectations about future inflation are also important because they affect how households and firms behave today. If households (which are also workers) expect that inflation will be higher in the future, then they will want to negotiate larger wage increases today, and firms will want to raise their prices today. So, how should a central banker respond to the higher unemployment and the inflationary pressure caused by an adverse supply shock, such as an oil price hike?

The answer depends on the assumptions in the model used. However, in many popular sticky-price models, central bankers should respond to an adverse supply shock by raising interest rates and promising to keep them high for a prolonged period. Higher interest rates induce households to cut current consumption and to save for future consumption instead. Facing lower demand for their product, firms must temper any price increases to avoid losing profits, which moderates current-period inflation. In addition, the promise to keep interest rates high for a prolonged period causes households and firms to expect that inflation will be lower in the future than it is today. Because they expect lower future inflation, households are prepared to negotiate lower nominal wage increases, which further allows firms to keep price increases down. Thus, through inflation expectations, the promise to keep monetary policy tight over the foreseeable future helps to reduce current inflation and, if the promised policy is implemented, future inflation also will be lower. In addition, because the policy tightening is spread out over time, it does not increase unemployment as much as it would if the tightening occurred all at once.

Unfortunately, this policy is time-inconsistent and will not be implemented. The problem is that the promise to keep monetary policy tight over the foreseeable future damps the inflationary impact of the adverse supply shock. But having promised a tight monetary policy, and having secured lower inflation today, the central banker now has less incentive to implement the promised tight policy in the future. Realizing that when the future actually arrives the central banker will not implement the tight monetary policy that it promised, households and firms will expect higher inflation in the future than if the tight policy were implemented. As a consequence, to damp the inflationary effect of the adverse supply shock, central bankers have to raise interest rates more today, generating more unemployment, than they would if they could commit themselves to implement the tight policy that they promised. In this scenario, the effect of the time-inconsistency is called stabilization bias because the time-inconsistency affects the central banker’s ability to stabilize inflation expectations and hence stabilize inflation itself. The stabilization bias adds to inflation’s variability, making inflation more difficult for households, firms, and the central bank, to predict.

To examine whether the stabilization bias caused by a central bank’s inability to commit to its optimal policy is important, Dennis and Söderström (2002) study a range of macroeconometric models. In these models, the stabilization bias manifests itself through greater inflation variability and lower output variability, much as if the central bank had an objective function that underweighted the importance of inflation stabilization and overweighted the importance of output stabilization. For the models that Dennis and Söderström looked at, a typical result is that distortions caused by stabilization bias are as undesirable, and as harmful, as a permanent 1.0 to 1.5 percentage point increase in inflation.

Conclusion

A discretionary inflation bias caused by time-inconsistency is one popular explanation for the great inflation experienced during the 1970s. If the only effect time-inconsistency had on economic outcomes were to raise the average inflation rate, then it might appear that, given today’s low inflation rates, time-inconsistency is not a problem that current policymakers need to contend with. However, as this Economic Letter has shown, in addition to its impact on the level of inflation, time-inconsistency also has important consequences for how the economy responds to shocks and for the volatility of inflation, output, and interest rates. To the extent that time-inconsistency leads to unnecessarily high inflation volatility and to a misallocation of resources through time, the causes of time-inconsistency and the associated benefits to precommitment cannot be easily ignored.

Richard Dennis
Economist

References
Barro, R., and D. Gordon. 1983. “Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics 12, pp.101-121.

Dennis, R., and U. Söderström. 2002. “How Important Is Precommitment for Monetary Policy?” FRBSF Working Paper 02-10. /economic-research/papers/2002/index.html

Ireland, P. 1999. “Does the Time-Inconsistency Problem Explain the Behavior of Inflation in the United States?” Journal of Monetary Economics 44(2), pp. 279-291.

Kydland, F., and E. Prescott. 1977. “Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans.” Journal of Political Economy 87, pp. 473-492.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

11 Comments

"..with the passing of time, policies that were determined to be optimal yesterday are no longer perceived to be optimal today and are not implemented."

Something about those who ignore history are doomed to repeat it then! Which is why the current policy of lower interest rates will likely come to haunt the global economy for decades to come. Lowering interest rates was a MASSIVE mistake as a solution to what current ails us, and time ( inconsistent or not!) is going to show us all that in the nastiest of ways.

Up
0

Exactly.

...lower yields are supposed to be because of the “stimulus” of central bank buying when in fact lower yields are instead the market pricing the increasing probability of failure of the buying program “stimulus.” In that way, both are actually on the same side. The market as well as central banks are all reacting to the same thing, with the latter powerless to do anything about it and the former, over time, increasingly aware of that established fact.

Even if you still believe, after all this, that central banks are the powerful instruments they are claimed to be, what would be your response to a world where they threw everything they had at the economic problem and achieved nothing tangible? You might pay a little higher premium than yesterday for liquidity, too. Read more

Up
0

Current predictions based on the recent Fed announcement that they will wind down their bond purchasing is that: over the next year they will slow then stop buying bonds, and that they will let the bonds they are holding expire and not buy any more. This is about a 10-20 year timescale for them to unload their assets with anticipated actions during economic slowdowns. That's a mighty debt hangover just for the Fed. It's going to be worse for those who are being sucked in by the low interest rates.

As I said a number of times last year by all means take advantage of the low interest rates but use them to pay down debt at an accelerated rate. A 15 year mortgage is going to be less risky than a 30 year.

Up
0

I thought low interest rates meant I was supposed to become a property speculator. Is that not the case?

Or if not a property speculator then at least be a success story for NZ Herald by having a $500K+ mortagage at the age of 21.

Up
0
Up
0

Enjoyed that (a lot) - thanks...

Up
0

Should we even bother to comment on this drivel from Robertson ?

Most countries on the planet would regard our employment rate as "full " employment .

We have over 90% in work and a massive list of vacancies , skill shortages from Doctors right down to burger flippers .

Our kids held down as many as 2 part time jobs WHILE AT UNIVERSITY !!!

There will always be some people who are not able to work ( such as woman with babies , or the disabled ) or people who cannot work (for example cannot hold down a job due substance abuse ) or those who simply dont want to work .

And we have those folk living in places where there is simply no work to be had like the many settlements up North with large unemployed populations .

Labour are wasting their time with this

Up
0

time inconsistency of optimal plans .

Fancy way of basically saying ..."an ignorance of first principles" and as BW mentions...an " ignorance of History. " or... " Cant see past their nose "

I'm thinking that Grant Robertson suffers from both..
I thought the "premise " of Bob Buckles questioning, expressed in the spirit of enquiry, was very valid and I thought Robertson was arrogant in being dismissive, and not even addressing the "premise",... and showed a side of himself ... and I suppose that is a side that all career politicians have.. ??

Up
0

You may or may not know much about forward guidance, but it has been of constant attention on the minds of policymakers. Further, policymakers themselves don’t seem to be able to define it, and because of it they can’t seem to solve the bond market puzzle. In orthodox economics, forward guidance is either
“Delphic” or “Odyssean.” As usual, there is a great deal of needless complication associated with either, for everything must be turned into a regression model or else economists are lost in common sense.

Delphic forward guidance is of the kind practiced by central banks before the 2008 global break. Pioneered in New Zealand, the central bank plainly states what it is thinking about the state of the world and therefore what guides the expected path of monetary policy. The problem with the “Delphic” version is in the more extreme policy cases, as much of the world found out before the GFC was ever finished.

If the central bank, for example, believes that its policies will be effective and maybe sharply so, then Delphic forward guidance can potentially thwart the policy before it actually becomes effective. In other words, if bond market participants get wind of these positive central bank expectations, bonds may selloff in “reflation”, thus raising market rates before the “stimulus” of low rates has a chance of doing its work.

The prospective solution to this problem is “Odyssean” forward guidance. Here, the central bank may recognize the potential opposing problem of Delphic guidance and overcome it by promising to keep up with “stimulus” even if the effects of “stimulus” start to become apparent. This was very clearly practiced in 2013 by the Fed who unusually committed to QE3, which was then thought open ended, tying it to the unemployment rate so as to keep the bond market from anticipating too much its future success. Read more

Up
0

If Labour bring this in.... it will simply "Politicize" Monetary Policy... which might be good for me as an Investor, but will be a negative thing, in the wider context..

just my view..

Up
0

Okay I am going to give my age away ............ look at Grant Robertson .............. he looks like and has the enthusiasm of Billy Bunter in the 1960's comics

Up
0