sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

The IMF's John Bluedorn says analysis suggests a sustained acceleration of wages and prices is unlikely

Investing / analysis
The IMF's John Bluedorn says analysis suggests a sustained acceleration of wages and prices is unlikely
Street crossing
Source: 123rf.com Copyright: defun

Inflation in some economies is rising at the fastest pace in four decades, while tight labor markets have boosted pay gains. That has raised concerns that these conditions could become self-reinforcing and lead to a wage-price spiral—a prolonged loop in which inflation leads to higher wage growth, fueling even higher inflation.

An examination of recent wage dynamics and the prospect of such a wage-price spiral are the subjects of an analytical chapter of our latest World Economic Outlook, which finds that, on average, the risks of a spiral are limited—so far. Three factors are working together to contain the risks: the underlying shocks to inflation are coming from outside the labor market, falling real wages are helping to reduce price pressures, and central banks are aggressively tightening monetary policy.

A look at history

To better understand these dynamics, we identified 22 situations in advanced economies over the past 50 years with conditions similar to 2021 when price inflation was rising, wage growth was positive, but real wages and the unemployment rate were flat or falling. These episodes didn’t lead to wage-price spirals on average.

Instead, inflation came down in subsequent quarters and nominal wages gradually rose, helping real wages recover.

Although the shocks hitting economies are unusual, these findings provide some reassurance that sustained wage-price spirals are rare. But that should not be cause for complacency by policymakers—there are differences across episodes, with some showing worse outcomes. Inflation in the United States, for example, kept rising and real wages fell for a while after 1979, when the economy was hit by further oil price hikes. The inflation trajectory changed only when the Federal Reserve raised interest rates sharply.

The role of expectations

How expectations are formed matters a lot for wage and price dynamics and affects what actions policymakers should take after an inflationary shock. Inflation expectations became more important in explaining wage dynamics over the second half of 2021, according to an empirical analysis.

To study how expectations affect the economy, we used a model-based analysis, calibrated to reflect economic conditions in the first half of this year and taking the policy rate path as given.

When businesses and households expect future inflation to be the same as it is today, an inflationary shock can lead workers to demand even more to compensate for perceived higher future inflation. This kind of backward-looking expectations process—what we refer to as fully adaptive—can lead inflation to rise and stay above the central bank’s inflation target for a prolonged period even if there are no additional price shocks.

By contrast, when people’s expectations reflect all available economic information—referred to as rational—businesses and households see the shock to wages and prices as temporary, leading wage growth and inflation to quickly move back towards target and stay anchored.

In most places, the reality lies somewhere between these extremes, with businesses and households looking at what happened in the past (weighing recent quarters more heavily) to learn about the economy’s structure and make predictions, referred to as adaptive learning. In this case, wage growth and inflation can take longer to come back to the central bank’s target than when expectations are rational, but faster than when they are fully adaptive.

In all these cases, real wages tend to go down initially as inflation outstrips wage growth, helping offset some of the cost-push shock that fueled inflation and working against a wage-price spiral. But if inflationary shocks start to come from the labor market itself—such as an unexpected, sharp uptick in wage indexation—that could moderate the effects of falling real wages, pushing up both wage growth and inflation for longer.

For monetary policymakers, understanding the expectations process is critical. When expectations are more backward-looking, monetary policy tightening—including through clear communications by the central bank—should be stronger and more front-loaded in response to an inflation shock.

In that sense, recent tightening actions by many central banks—calibrated to economy-specific circumstances—are encouraging. They will help to prevent high inflation from becoming entrenched and inflation from deviating from target for too long.


John Bluedorn is a Deputy Division Chief on the World Economic Outlook in the IMF’s Research Department. This blog is based on Chapter 2 of the October 2022 World Economic Outlook, “Wage Dynamics Post-COVID-19 and Wage-Price Spiral Risks.” The authors of the report are Silvia Albrizio, Jorge Alvarez, Alexandre Balduino Sollaci, John Bluedorn (lead), Allan Dizioli, Niels-Jakob Hansen, and Philippe Wingender, with support from Youyou Huang and Evgenia Pugacheva. This is a re-post of an article that ran on the IMF blog.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

4 Comments

So in other words, workers are absorbing the costs of price increases and their purchasing power is declining?

Gosh when you put it like that, it almost sounds like a bad thing! 

Up
1

Spot on, employees having PAYE deducted have little recourse to increasing their salary outside of leaving and taking a new role with a new employer. Result being good employees are leaving for higher salaries putting price pressure on employers to pay more.

Up
0

Almost everybody loses when inflation is high: 

- asset owners, due to the increasing interest rates environment

- conservative savers, as bond prices are butchered, and term deposit rates do not cover for the rising inflation 

- workers, as pay rates struggle to keep pace with rising inflation

- many businesses, in particular the ones operating in a competitive environment, as they struggle to pass on increasing labour and material costs, see their products becoming less affordable for the average wage-earner, and the financial costs associated with running a business increase significantly 

- debtors, as they see the costs of servicing their debts skyrocketing 

Very few individual and operators manage to thrive in a rising inflation environment. The whole economy suffers. Entrenched high inflation is (excluding a depression) one of the worst things that can happen to an economy. And it is a very painful and lengthy process to control and eliminate. Unfortunately, the clowns at the helm of the RBNZ and in Government do not appear to have any idea (or they pretend they don't) of the highly damaging effects of persistent high inflation to the overall economy and society.

 

 

Up
0

Isn't this just another way to say workers got screwed this year by not having the real value of their wages maintained - yet again?

Compare the change in the real value of the median wage over time. No surprise that an average family can't live comfortably just from the median wage earnings from one full time job these days.

Up
0