sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Te wiki o te tāke: Depreciating buildings; who are taxed the heaviest? and the OECD says housing should be taxed

Public Policy / analysis
Te wiki o te tāke: Depreciating buildings; who are taxed the heaviest? and the OECD says housing should be taxed
types of buildings
Source: 123rf.com Copyright: klavapuk


Inland Revenue has released Interpretation Statement IS 22/04 on claiming depreciation on buildings. Critical to this issue is determining the meaning of a “building” for depreciation purposes and the distinction between residential and non-residential buildings. The Interpretation Statement addresses this issue when it sets out when depreciation may be claimed for non-residential building and also for some fitter. It confirms that no depreciation is available for residential buildings.

The Interpretation Statement then sets out where you can find the right depreciation rate for buildings when fit outs attached to buildings may be depreciable. How to treat an improvement of a building for depreciation purposes. And then finally, what happens when the building is disposed of or its use changes?

To recap, depreciation for all buildings was reduced to zero, with effect from the 2011-12 income year. Back in 2020 as part of the initial response to the pandemic, the Government reintroduced depreciation for non-residential buildings with effect from the start of the 2020-21 income year. Generally, the depreciation rate is 2% on a diminishing value basis, or 1.5% on a straight-line basis. Some other depreciation rates may be used where the building has a shorter than normal useful economic life. Examples would be barns, portable buildings or hot houses. Additionally, it's possible to claim a special rate if the building is used in an unusual way.

Now for depreciation purposes “building’ retains its ordinary meaning which means anything that is structural to the building or used for weatherproofing the building. The Interpretation Statement emphasizes that whether a building is residential or non-residential is an all or nothing test, it’s an all or nothing test. If the building is non-residential depreciation is available, otherwise not,  there's no apportionment.

Residential buildings are any places mainly used as a place of residence. This includes garages or sheds included with that building. Places used as residential residences for independent living in retirement villages and rest homes are residential buildings are is short stay accommodation where there's less than four separate units.

On the other hand, non-residential building includes buildings used predominantly for commercial and industrial purposes, but not residential buildings. This also includes hotels, motels, inns, boarding houses, serviced apartments and camping grounds. Retirement villages and rest homes where places are not being used for independent living are non-residential buildings as is short stay accommodation where there are four or more separate units.

If improvements are made to a building, you must treat it as a separate item of depreciable property in the first tax year. Then you can either continue to treat it as a separate item of depreciable property or simply add it to the building by increasing the adjusted taxable value of the building.

In some cases, a fit out can be separately depreciated depending on the nature of the building and the nature of the fit out. Where the fit out is considered structural to the building or used to weather proof the building it must be treated as part of building and not depreciated separately. Fit outs are depreciable in a wholly non-residential building and sometimes in a mixed-use building. But remember, the key point is that depreciation is not available under any circumstances for a residential building. So overall, this is a useful Interpretation Statement and is also, as has become the norm, accompanied by a very handy fact sheet.

The agencies tackling organised crime and its tax evasion

Moving on, last week I discussed a suggestion by ACT Party leader David Seymour to use Inland Revenue against the gangs. I looked at the powers available to Inland Revenue and discussed how practical his proposal was. To summarise, Inland Revenue has extensive powers which would be useful in tackling gangs and organised crime. However, this is a resource intensive approach which probably in Inland Revenue’s view, would divert its attention from other areas it considers equally important.

This prompted some discussion in the comments section and thank you again to all those who contributed. As I said, my view is Inland Revenue probably thinks other agencies, such as the Police, are better suited for this activity. But it will cooperate with those agencies. Its annual reports make clear they pass information to other agencies. So Inland Revenue is probably working on this matter in the background.

It was interesting just to take a look to see what other agencies were doing in this space and get a gauge of what’s happening.  A key tool for the Police is the use of restraining orders to seize assets. According to the Police's Annual Report for the year ended 30th June 2021 the value of restraints for the year totalled just over $100 million, including nearly $30 million seized from anti-money laundering.

The Department of Internal Affairs also has responsibilities for anti-money laundering, as it's a key regulator on that. Its Annual Report to June 2021 indicates that perhaps it could do more in this space, as its budget for its regulatory services for the year was set at $52 million, but it only spent $44 million.

And then when you look at the DIA’s performance metrics, such as desk-based reviews of reporting entities, it’s supposed to be targeting between 150 and 350 such reviews annually, but managed only 219 for the year, up from 198 in the previous year. And on-site visits were meant to be somewhere between 70 and 180 but came in at 79. To be fair these were probably disrupted by the impact of COVID 19.

Still, there are other agencies involved in pursuing gangs including Customs who will also be very interested. Inland Revenue will be playing a role, it shares information with these other agencies. So even if it's not wielding a very big stick publicly, it's working in the background.

The interaction of tax and abatements on social assistance

Now tax has been in the news a lot recently with the election coming up even though it’s still just over a year away probably. National and the ACT Party have both set out they would proposed some tax cuts. Last Saturday, Max Rashbrooke, a senior associate at the Institute of Governance and Policy Studies, who has written quite a lot on wealth and taxation put out some counter proposals to National and ACT’s proposals.

He suggested that really the focus should be on middle income earners. And he made a suggestion, for example, that we could have a $5,000 income tax free threshold, something we see in other jurisdictions. Britain's is just over £12,500, Australia’s is A$18,200 and the US has a slightly different thing. It gives you a standard deduction of US$12,000. But anyway, let's take that comment elsewhere. And Max suggested that something could be done in that space.

But it got me thinking about the question of who does actually pay the highest tax rates in the country. And the answer isn't those on over $180,000 where the tax rate is 39%, it’s actually more around $50,000 mark if those people are receiving any form of government assistance, such as Working for Families. If they have a student loan as well, then an additional 12% of their salary after tax gets deducted.      

The interaction of tax and abatements on social assistance, such as the family tax credit and parental tax credit can mean in some cases, the effective marginal tax rate for some families is more than 100% on every extra dollar they're earning. This is an issue which the Welfare Expert Advisory Group touched on, but the Tax Working Group wasn't allowed to address. But it’s a huge problem.

Take, for example, someone earning $50,000, just above the $48,000 threshold where the tax rate goes from 17% to 30%. And that, by the way, is the rate where I think we need to focus our attention on adjustments to thresholds and tax rates. At that level every extra dollar they're earning is taxed at 30%. If they've got a student loan then they pay a further 12%. If they have a young family and are receiving Working for Families tax credits, then these are abated at 27%. Incidentally, the abatement threshold is $42,700. So that means that that person is on a marginal tax rate of 69%. Definitely not nice.

Then there's a separate credit, the Best Start tax credit which has a separate abatement regime in addition to the Working for Families abatement regime I just explained. So that's why people could be suffering an effective marginal tax rate of over 100%.

In my view, this is the area where we really need to be thinking about changing the tax system, because to compound matters, governments have been very cynical about not adjusting thresholds for inflation, something I've raised repeatedly in the past.

Working for Families thresholds were adjusted for inflation every year until National was elected in 2008. Starting in the 2010 Budget they started freezing thresholds. They also increased the abatement rate which used to be 20% and is now 27%. The current Working for Families abatement threshold is $42,700, which is less than what someone working full time on the minimum wage will earn annually

Looking at student loans the threshold where repayments start in 2009 was $19,084. That is now $21,268 but for a long period of time under the last government it was frozen. National also increased the repayment rate from 10% to 12% in 2013.

So this is an area where governments of both hues have been really quite cynical in my view, and where a lot of serious thought needs to go in about trying to address the inequities that have arisen. The Welfare Expert Advisory Group suggested the abatement rate should be 10% on incomes between $48,000 and $65,000, then increase to 15% before rising to 50% on family incomes over $160,000. (Yes, large families with that level of income could be receiving social assistance in some instances).

There’s a lot of work to be done in this space and inflation adjustments to thresholds is something that should be done anyway. But I think we need to think carefully around the thresholds and how the interaction with social assistance works. At the moment we're not getting that sort of analysis from either any of the main parties and that's disappointing, as it’s something that really needs to be addressed.

Why the FER deals with recurrent taxes better

And finally this week, just hot off the press is an OECD report on Housing Taxation in OECD countries. This makes for some interesting reading. Briefly, the report is concerned about how housing wealth is mostly concentrated amongst high income, high-wealth and older households. And in some cases, they believe that a disproportionately large share of owner-occupied housing wealth is held by this group. There's been unprecedented growth in house prices, not just in New Zealand, but across the whole OECD, making housing market access increasingly difficult for younger generations.

In terms of suggestions the OECD believes is that housing taxes are “of growing importance given the pressure on governments to raise revenues, improve the functioning of housing markets and combat inequality.” The report notes the way housing taxes are designed often reduces their efficiency. Recurrent property taxes, such as rates, are often levied on outdated property values, which significantly reduces their revenue potential. This also reduces how equitable they are because where housing prices have rocketed up, people are underpaying based on current values. And conversely people in places where prices are falling or have been stagnant are paying more relative to those in richer areas.

One of the suggestions the report makes is that the role of recurrent taxes on immovable property should be strengthened, by ensuring that they are levied on regularly updated property values. And this is one of these reasons why Professor Susan St John and I have been promoting the Fair Economic Return approach. One of the strongpoints of our proposal would be strengthening the role of recurrent taxes.

Capping a capital gains tax exemption on the sale of a primary residence

Another proposal would not at all popular. It is to consider capping the capital gains tax exemption on the sale of main houses so that the highest value gains are taxed. This should strengthen progressivity in the system and reduce some of the upward pressures. This is what happens the U.S. There is an US$250,000 exemption on the main home per person, and above that the gains are taxed. There's no reason why we shouldn't have a similar type exemption here if we want to introduce a capital gains tax. But as I said, that would be particularly unpopular.

The OECD also believes there should be better targeted incentives for energy efficient housing, because housing, according to this report has a significant carbon footprint, maybe 22% of global final energy consumption and 17% of energy related CO2 emissions.

So, there’s a lot to consider in this report, and we come back to it and consider it in more detail. But again, it sort of comes into this point we've talked about repeatedly on the podcast, the question of broadening the tax base and the taxation of capital. These issues aren't going to go away, particularly when you consider, as I mentioned a few minutes ago, how very high effective marginal tax rates are paid by people on modest incomes who may not have any housing. No doubt we'll be discussing all these issues sometime again in the future.

Well, that's all for this week. I’m Terry Baucher and you can find this podcast on my website www.baucher.tax or wherever you get your podcasts. Thank you for listening and please send me your feedback and tell your friends and clients.

Until next time kia pai te wiki, have a great week!


*Terry Baucher is an Auckland-based tax specialist with 25 years experience. He works with individuals and entities who have complex tax issues. Prior to starting his own business, he spent six years with one of the "Big Four' accountancy firms including a period advising Australian businesses how to do business in New Zealand. You can contact him here.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

26 Comments

No matter how frequently or assertively international organisations or tax working groups recommend a housing tax it will remain political suicide.

Up
2

Probably right until home ownership rate drop below 50%.

Up
2

Just to point out the student loan 12% deduction is for repayment of a loan - not tax.

 

Up
4

The outcome for the intent of the discussion is still the same. It's also still a horrifically outdated system. 

Up
1

Quite right. After paying their costs, self employed people pay 15% GST, then their 30% income tax, then another 15% GST on all their purchases. Just too much. No wonder the government has a bit of trouble with making people comply with such theivery. Even wage earners pay their income tax, then the 15% GST. This has to stop. There has to be a severe audit on what government should actually be responsible for, and how few government workers should be required to run our government.

Up
1

While it's repayment of a loan, it's definitely a form of tax on tertiary study which was introduced in 1992.

Also annual student loan draw down is less than $1b per year.  Meanwhile we have no issue shoveling $16b per year to pensioners regardless of need, all funded by future tax payers who have a 12% noose around their neck for trying to better themselves.  

Up
1

Spare me this old crap. Please

Up
0

Guilty conscience?  

Up
0

Such high effective marginal tax rates give a huge financial incentive to evade it. Then we end up like Greece.

A tradie diligently following the law works all week plus Saturday morning. After allowing for gst, 30% income tax, and 27% wff abatement, he gets to keep 37% of the amount charged to the customer. His illegal mate doing a cashie gets to keep all of it. So he gets as much after just 2 days work. 

The same distortion applies with a PAYE paying wage earner buying a personal item compared to a business owner putting the same personal item through the company books.

Now a few people will break the law to avoid even a small amount of tax, but most people would rather do the right thing. There comes a point though where the tax is so high that those normally law abiding people will succumb to temptation. No good comes of that.

 

 

Up
5

That’s like saying that while a pharmacist pays tax, a drug dealer doesn’t. Moving on, all this talk of credits etc paints a picture of a horribly complex system. A tax free threshold of $5000 for singles, $8000 for joint income, and an extra $4000 for each of the first two children would be much simpler. $16,000 for a family of four before they start paying any tax.  Student loan repayments are keeping a generation in poverty and bloating the education sector (I was a tertiary lecturer, 12 contact hours, 20 weeks’ in class. Marking done on wet days at home, and some nominal research during the hols, which I was paid extra for. Same with my colleagues, probably more so). Forgive most of the student debt and tighten up the criteria regarding eligibility of courses. Fees would drop, and youngsters would be able to flow more cash back into the real economy. And stop the punitive interest charges on those who work overseas. Many youngsters are forced overseas by the lack of opportunity in this country. 

Up
1

"Capping a capital gains tax exemption on the sale of a primary residence"

A mega landlord is likely able to absorb a capital gains tax. But not your average homeowner. Imagine having to sell, as circumstances change, and finding that after tax, there is less money to buy another house. 

Variations like capping, my guess is that it'll be unpopular.

Even "have nots" have offspring/family to think about.

Income equality (or wealth equality) via capital gains tax. Nay.

Up
1

Many people would never be mortgage free under such a scheme. The Big Four will love it, just as accountants such as Mr Baucher love ever more complex tax schemes. Do doctors want a disease free society, do police and lawyers want an end to crime?

Up
3

Sounds like a disincentive to swap houses amongst each other at ever increasing prices to me.

Isn't that the point, demolishing the wealth through housing world NZ loves so much.

Up
0

How are more taxes on houses and capital gains going to help young people buy houses and build their net worth?

Up
3

Young civil servants in Wellington, maybe. 

Up
0

Maybe build your net worth through other means... God forbid.

Up
0

You will own nothing and be happy. Have you seen what they are doing to farms with added costs for esg. Same thing is coming for housing.

Up
1

Stating the bleedin’ obvious: 

“Briefly, the report is concerned about how housing wealth is mostly concentrated amongst high income, high-wealth and older households.”

Older people are richer than younger people because they had longer to save and accumulate assets. And high income people can afford better homes, cars, health care etc. They are probably better looking, more intelligent and better at sport. Haven’t Mr Baucher and Ms St John heard of genes? 

Up
4

...and of course, all of this is less of an issue if the same opportunities are available to young people as they were to older people. But they aren't, and this has been proven using objective statistics, over and over again.

But sure, tell me how young people are going to save over the course of their working lives when they have to borrow four times as much as their parents did to buy a house and service it on wages that don't keep up with general inflation, let alone housing inflation.

Up
4

"Rah rah rah something about 18% interest rates" [Insert anecdote where someone borrowed more than the median multiple] etc

If someone asked me if I'd pay 18% interest on $200k or 3.5% on $600k over 25 years (both payments are basically the same) then I'd take the 18%.  Why?  Because it's much easier to make a dent in the principal with lump sum payments, and wage inflation works a lot quicker to reduce the debt burden.  

Up
0

Yes you are right the young people are going to have to accept a lower standard of living going forward

Up
0

Terry - income related rents is another  hidden 'tax' or sorts in that it affects money in hand after rent is adjusted for increased in income above thresholds.

Up
1

Thanks Terry for drawing attention to the invisible work disincentives built into our system through overlapping abatements of many kinds. Like many organisations, CPAG has tried to get attention to this issue over many years. With fixed thresholds the poverty trap has become progressively worse.  The rise of the WFF abatement to 27% makes a further mockery of the claim that Working for Families (WFF) is designed to 'make work pay'. The treatment of student loans is a disgrace.

When  you say "The Welfare Expert Advisory Group suggested the abatement rate should be 10% on incomes between $48,000 and $65,000, then increase to 15% before rising to 50% on family incomes over $160,000", it must be noted that this reduced abatement was only in the context of the new expensive tax rebate the "Earned income tax credit' that WEAG proposed. This new tax credit was an unnecessary  mistake in the eyes of CPAG. It was only because the EITC was going to add 15% to the abatement problem that the abatement rate of WFF was to be reduced. Oh what a tangled web we weave..... 

 

Up
0

Property taxes are supposed to be for the purposes of providing services to the property owner/occupier  and not a system of wealth distribution.

Up
1

The only reason for any tax is to fund the running of government. If a 5% tax on politicians properties capital gains was enough, then that is all the tax we would need. The obvious lie about equitable  taxation spread amongst various sectors of our communities is shown by the equally obvious fact that when taxes are increased for one sector of the community, there is never a reduction for any other sector as would be the case if the reason for the extra tax was just to square things up between the different sectors.

Up
0

Capital gains tax on residential property rewards the government as they keep juicing the housing market to cause capital gains.  It is just like GST in that the more inflation you get, the more GST is paid. The government wins, and the people lose. 

Up
0