sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Given that it is increasingly difficult to get affordable earthquake insurance, we may have to radically revise the system, economist Brian Easton says

Public Policy / opinion
Given that it is increasingly difficult to get affordable earthquake insurance, we may have to radically revise the system, economist Brian Easton says
earthquakerf1
Source: 123rf.com. Copyright: westamult

This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.


Suppose you are exposed to a risk that you cannot protect yourself from. You might set aside a capital sum which would cover the loss if the event occurred. But if the loss was your dwelling from an earthquake, you’d have to put aside its entire value, effectively doubling the cost of the house even though the probability of a total wipeout is low (or so you hope).

Instead we use insurance to cover the contingency. Broadly there are two kinds of insurance that are sometimes traced back to two instances (illustrative, but not entirely historically accurate).

One involved a group of Swiss farmers who agreed that if any of them suffered a loss of a cow, the loss would be shared among all of them. Observe that such social sharing can only work if the shock does not affect a large part of the group.

The second kind of insurance is said to have led to the development of Lloyd's of London. It involves paying a fixed sum to someone to take the risk of an event happening. The counter-party covers a lot of similar events and gambles that only some will happen, with the expectation that the total claims are less than the fixed sums paid to them; if it does not, they make a loss. Typically they, often a corporation, take on a portfolio of such gambles in the likelihood that an earthquake in Wellington won’t occur at the much the same time as ones in San Francisco and Tokyo. It is possible the insurance company will not be able to cover its losses and goes bankrupt. (AMI had state help to prevent it going under when it was too exposed to the Canterbury earthquakes. The world’s largest insurer, AIG had to be nationalised by the US during the GFC.) In which case the insurer would lose their cover.

It is much more complex than this, but the important thing here is that there are these three responses: self, share (or social) and shift insurance. Of these ‘share’ and ‘shift’ are the significant policy options (although if there is an excess to one’s insurance that is ‘self’).

In 1993 Earthquake Commission Act New Zealand made a dramatic change to its earthquake insurance changing the balance between share and shift. I focus on dwellings – there were also changes to commercial buildings – and I simplify.

Before, the essence of a dwelling’s earthquake recovery protection was a share scheme in which the risk was covered by the New Zealand government. Insurance levies were paid to the Earthquake and War Damage Commission; if there was damage, the EWDC paid for it. If the EWDC had insufficient reserves, the government (taxpayer) covered the deficit. So the residual individual earthquake risk was shared across the entire New Zealand community.

After 1993 only the first $100,000 of damage was covered by the renamed Earthquake Commission (EQC) to which insurance was paid. (The government has recently hiked the level to $300,000. The $100,000 in 1993 would purchase about $200,000 of building construction today.) The rest of the earthquake protection has to be purchased from private insurers. Basically, since 1993 there has been a rebalancing from sharing to shifting – a privatisation of earthquake protection.

(EQC insurance also covers other major catastrophes such as natural landslips, volcanic eruptions, hydrothermal activity, tsunamis and the impact of storms and floods on residential land.)

There were numerous reasons justifying the change. The minister in charge of the bill was Ruth Richardson so that there would have been a neoliberal-minimalist state element among them. (The change was discussed by the Rogernomics Government.)

The winding down of the sharing state was happening in other policy areas. The Richardson-Shipley ‘reform of the welfare state’ was a reversion to the charitable aid which had preceded the 1898 Pensions Act, the first major social insurance in New Zealand.

The notion of social insurance, where certain burdens are shared across the nation, hardly appears in today’s rhetoric of even the Labour Party. When did it last use Nash’s ‘the young, the old and the sick will have the first call upon the state’? An exception is the proposed social insurance for the unemployed who have been made redundant. One is struck how the dominant criticism is from minimalists who see the levies as a tax, rather than a means of sharing the burden of adjustment across all workers. (I assume they would not object if private insurance did this, but it wont.)

Another justification for the 1993 earthquake legislation was the Treasury trying to minimise its exposure to risk because it felt the taxpayer was overcommitted. It worried that it might not be able to fund other costs associated with a major disaster, such as social welfare payments and the restoration of government facilities.

Following the Canterbury earthquakes the Key-English Government chose to fund its reconstruction out of current revenue rather than imposing a special levy, say on income tax, justified by the entire nation sharing the burden. That would have been the approach of the traditional welfare state. (The consequence was that public spending was squeezed; we are paying the cost of the social damage it caused through to this today.)

My view is that a role of the government is to do things which the private market cannot do effectively. There were private insurance companies willing to sell earthquake insurance – take the risk – so there was a case for changing the balance from share to shift. Note that the insurance companies do not take all the risk but shift some on by reinsuring with others offshore, as does the EQC.

Thirty years later the system is not working well. The Canterbury and Kaikoura earthquakes have indicated that seriously damaging earthquakes are more likely than we once thought. Apparently a period of earthquake quiescence has come to an end; there is increasing uncertainty about the future risks of these catastrophes and reinsurers are becoming more wary. (Climate change is another source of increased uncertainty.)

The situation is further complicated by there being only three significant private insurers, which means the market is not fully competitive and may work less than smoothly.

In any case, private earthquake insurance is becoming increasingly expensive. For instance Wellington apartment buildings of a certain age and height are suffering extraordinary increases. In one case I saw, private earthquake insurance costs have increased since the Kaikoura earthquakes by over eightfold.

It is not the private insurers’ fault; they cannot find cheap reinsurers. The risks since the Canterbury earthquakes have become much more uncertain. They may be able to find a reinsurer but not at an acceptable price while the local domestic insurer may concerned about being too concentrated – as the AMI experience demonstrated. The best approach in such circumstances is prevention, but retrospective fitting of older buildings can be very expensive.

Perhaps we should revisit the 1993 decision. Should we change the balance, going back to greater use of sharing the risk across the nation rather than depending on shifting all of it offshore?

Insurance is a complex area. We have had numerous inquiries into the operation of the EQC but not a single one as looked at the self-share-shift balance. Hopefully, we will get around to it before the next great earthquake.


*Brian Easton, an independent scholar, is an economist, social statistician, public policy analyst and historian. He was the Listener economic columnist from 1978 to 2014. This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

11 Comments

If the approach to moral hazard is to spread the cost when the risk is attached to a physical location, then maybe the physical location is the problem, not the fact no one wants to offer insurance against it for sensible money. We're not talking about the relatively low life-time risk of a volcanic eruption which might affect a small part of Auckland here. 

I have a hard time understanding why poorer, low-risk areas should underwrite insurance for places that the international market can't or won't touch. At some point, there has to be a rational conversation about whether Wellington is the right place for Wellington.

Up
0

As Christchurch has shown, it is more than just Wgtn though. Our entire country sits on an active fault line. Even Auckland is <200km from the main fault line. An 8-9 or even greater in the right (or wrong place) and Auckland is in as much trouble as anywhere else.

Overlay that with the volcanoes (and let's not forget Taupo) NZ as a whole is not likely to be viable for long term habitation.

Insurance works within a specific timeframe. It simply isn't designed for ongoing risk.

 

 

Up
3

The risk of an eruption in Auckland is something like 1% over an 80 year period. There is more risk posed to Auckland from Taranaki or Ruapehu depending on prevailing winds. The likelihood of either of the two main faults that pose a risk to Auckland producing more than a 7.5Mw quake in any person's lifetime is currently thought to be small. The risk of the Apline Fault rupturing is greater than 30% over a 50 year period. These are not the same levels of risk.

That aside, if quake risk is so inherent then knowingly persisting with a city on top of congruent faults with many potential triggers that have already proven to impact the city directly is even harder to justify. All options should be on the table. Frankly I'd support using the Navy to shell it, but I suppose moving Wellington should also be considered. 

Up
0

The risk numbers are just guesses at best, and really are irrelevant. The fact is it can and will happen as demonstrated in Chch.

Our navy has neither the capacity nor the capability to shell Wellington. All you need is for the council to continue as normal and it will be empty in 10 years anyway due to lack of water, sewerage, and a dying CBD.

Up
4

That does raise the question though, of a city largely in need of massive renewal for fairly basic infrastructure... why not have the conversation about moving or relocating key bits of it now?

The risk numbers are best guesses, but in geological terms, the Apline Fault is has a preposterously high likelihood of erupting, even on a human scale. 

Up
0

"why not have the conversation about moving or relocating key bits of it now?"

The money is the issue. The minute you announce it all land/assets/etc... in Wellington are worth Zero. So not like you could just sell and move So, who compensates them?

Up
0

Maybe the free market should decide. 90% of Californians do not have Earthquake Insurance. Typical insurance there does not cover earthquake damage. Insurers want that risk to be covered separately. $2.50 - $5.50 per $1000 of cover. Depending on the earthquake risk in your property location. 

So $500000 could cost you $2750 per year. Just for earthquake cover. Normal insurance on top of that.

Is it unreasonable for Wellington home owners to pay similar rates? Or should Auckland home owners continue to subsidize via EQC levies for an event that is a certainty for Wellington and an outside chance for Auckland.

Up
1

Home insurance in NZ has become a cash transfer mechanism - extracting hundreds of millions of dollars per year in profits from households. If we had a major Hikurangi fault eruption that wiped out thousands of homes, do we really think that the insurance companies would step up? Is an insurance industry that risk assesses for 12 months only even useful when we have such obvious medium-term risks? Is it not ridiculous to rely on investment funds made up of shares in companies that could be worthless in a few minutes if the proverbial really hits the fan?

The solution IMHO is to:

  • contract or employ a crack team of actuaries to set premiums at the property level based on a 20-year timeframe (probably easiest to pay the insurance companies)
  • nationalise home insurance and collect premiums alongside Local Govt rates
  • stagger the transition to the new 20-year risk premiums over 5 - 10 years
  • invest heavily in creating resilient local supply chains (with maximum use of local materials) so that we can build new houses with minimal imports. Stockpile non-perishable building materials and design and test multiple rapid build house designs
  • if there is a major disaster, pause construction of non-essential work and use the Crown balance sheet to fund the re-build. Note that domestic supply of materials and services would ensure that Govt investment stays onshore and washes back as taxes

 

Up
1

insurance companies engage in reinsurance deals (underwriting exchanges) across national borders. 

a company in Germany buys a pct of business in nz and the nz company buys a corresponding pct of that companies book of business. thereby spreading the geographical risks. the impact of of the chch quake was that this reinsurance has become very expensive. 

your premiums would need to be 2 or 3 times greater than what they are now if the companies didn't invest in stocks, bonds, and real estate. the income generated from these investments subsidizes the premiums of every policy holder.

Up
0

Useful, thank. My point is that we don't need premiums or a fund-backed insurance model at all in NZ - we should just treat houses like roads, water infrastructure, etc - if they break we pay to fix them. The 'premium' would effectively be a tax used primarily to influence peoples / business decisions.      

Up
0

the stories comments about the ami situation is materially incorrect.

ami insurance was not bailed out by the govt as the company was wiped out. the bulk of its assets were held in chch commercial real estate which was flattened by the quake. this left every ami customer in New zealand with no insurance.

the govt stepped in and arranged the urgent sale of the ami brand name, plus all unencumbered policies to iag. this allowed the people in nz who had insurance though the old ami business to still be covered. the total loss policies were moved into the eqc/southern response structure where they were managed/paid out.

as an aside, I recall hearing about conversations with the ceo of the former ami company where he was very reluctant to expand his business into wellington due to earthquake risks. ironic...

Up
0