sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Auckland is NZ’s "primate city" but its potential remains caged in by poor planning and vision

Public Policy / opinion
Auckland is NZ’s "primate city" but its potential remains caged in by poor planning and vision
Auckland skyline at dusk

The recent report comparing Auckland to nine international peer cities delivered an uncomfortable truth: our largest city is falling behind, hampered by car dependency, low-density housing and “weak economic performance”.

The Deloitte State of the City analysis was no surprise to anyone who has watched successive governments treat the city as a problem to manage, rather than an engine to fuel.

The report’s findings were stark: Auckland rates 82nd out of 84 cities globally for pedestrian friendliness, and its car-dependent transport system is more carbon-intensive and slower to decarbonise than peer cities.

This is the direct result of decades of planning failures, including what urban researchers call the 1970s “great down-zoning” which halved central Auckland’s housing capacity.

This isn’t just Auckland’s problem. When we mismanage what geographers call a “primate city,” it reveals our fundamental misunderstanding of how modern economies work.

The concept of the primate city was formalised by geographer Mark Jefferson in 1939. Such cities are defined as being “at least twice as large as the next largest city and more than twice as significant”.

Auckland fits this definition perfectly. With more than 1.7 million people, it is over four times larger than Christchurch or the greater Wellington region. The city accounts for 34% of New Zealand’s population and is projected to hit 40% of the working-age population by 2048.

Auckland contributes 38% of New Zealand’s gross domestic product and its per-capita GDP is 15% higher than the rest of the country’s. Its most productive area, the central business district, enjoys a 40% productivity premium over the national average.

To economists, these numbers represent the “agglomeration benefits” research shows primate cities generate. It is the economic effect of combining businesses, talent and infrastructure.

Yet New Zealand systematically underinvests in the very place generating this outsized economic contribution.

A pattern of infrastructure failure

Auckland’s infrastructure deficit follows a predictable pattern. The City Rail Link, while progressing, has grown from an initial budget of NZ$2-3 billion to $5.5 billion, with opening delayed until 2026.

Light rail was cancelled entirely after years of planning. A second harbour crossing has been studied for decades without a shovel hitting dirt. Each represents billions in opportunity costs while congestion worsens.

This goes well beyond project mismanagement. It is a deep structural problem.

The Infrastructure Commission-Te Waihanga identifies a $210 billion national infrastructure shortfall, with Auckland bearing a disproportionate burden despite generating a disproportionately high level of revenue.

International research by the OECD shows successful countries treat metropolitan regions as engines of national growth, not a burden.

The ‘Wellington problem’

Public policy expert Ian Shirley called it the “Wellington Problem”: the way Auckland’s governance became an obsession for politicians and bureaucrats based in Wellington.

The tension dates to 1865 when the capital was moved from Auckland to Wellington, establishing a pattern where political power was deliberately separated from economic power.

Auckland loses an estimated $415.35 million annually in GST collected on rates. This goes to Wellington and into government revenue rather than being reinvested locally. Central government properties in Auckland, worth $36.3 million in rates, are exempt from payment while still using Auckland’s infrastructure.

When Auckland speaks with “one voice” through its unified council, Wellington responds with legislative overrides.

The recent National Land Transport Programme, for example, cut Auckland’s transport funding by $564 million. Mayor Wayne Brown said the government’s transport policy “makes zero sense for Auckland”.

Learning from others

The contrast with international approaches reveals just how counterproductive New Zealand’s approach has been.

London has an integrated Transport for London authority with congestion charging powers, generating £136 million annually for reinvestment. Paris is investing more than €35 billion in the Grand Paris Express transit project.

Japan’s “Quality Infrastructure Investment principles include ¥13.2 trillion in regional infrastructure investment. Australia’s A$120 billion infrastructure programme explicitly recognises its largest cities contribute over 50% of GDP and require proportional investment.

Research has shown excessive urban concentration in one country can create problems. But denying the primate city resources only leads to a “deterioration in the quality of life” that drags down the entire national economy.

The solution lies in making strategic investments that maximise the benefits of agglomeration while managing any negative costs to the national economy.

Growing pains

Auckland isn’t a problem to be managed, it is an asset to be leveraged. Every successful developed economy has learned this lesson. Paris generates 31% of France’s GDP and gets treated accordingly.

Seoul produces 23% of South Korea’s output and receives massive infrastructure investment. Tokyo drives Japan’s economy.

The international evidence is unambiguous: countries that strategically invest in their primate cities achieve higher productivity growth and maintain competitive advantages.

Auckland doesn’t need sympathy or special treatment. It needs what every primate city in every successful economy gets: infrastructure investment proportional to its economic contribution, governance structures that reflect its scale, and political leadership that understands agglomeration economics.

The question isn’t whether Auckland is too big. The question is whether New Zealand is big enough to nurture its primate city.


Timothy Welch is Senior Lecturer in Urban Planning, University of Auckland, Waipapa Taumata Rau. This article is republished from The Conversation under a Creative Commons license. Read the original article.

The Conversation

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

4 Comments

Parochialism has been a major contributor to development and the current situation in Auckland. An element missing in this article. A similar situation in Hawkes Bay between Hastings and Napier.

I can't recall how many territorial local authorities (TLAs) made up "Auckland " before central government pushed through the super city amalgamation. The existence of those TLAs stymied a vision and coordinated development of Auckland of Auckland as the model the author says is needed. How long has it taken London or Paris to reach their respective "exemplary" positions. And how has geographical location within each nations land mass made it more readily achievable?

The author is quoting GDP and productivity stats that are misleading in my opinion, if not questionable. GDP measures the money go round, so with a high population,  it is of course, a much bigger merry go round than other centres. For example,  the fuel and paid time wastage functioning in a city with such deficient transport infrastructure, still counts in the GDP stats. With other regional locations, transport efficiencies reduce per tonne cost and therefore less money is "going round and round" but export product is being shipped more cost efficiently with positive effects on cost of sales in export earnings. 

Also, because the likes of Fonterra is headquartered in Auckland, does that displace the real location of the GDP contribution from the Fonterra industrial complex?

IMO another way of looking at this is to recognise that the experiment of Auckland being the power house of the NZ economy is doomed. Instead, a NZ development strategy would be better focused on ensuring investment in locations that give higher efficiency to exports.

Up
0

I think a telling statistic is that commonly the next largest city is half the size. But Auckland is so much larger than the other cities.  I struggle to think of another country which has 40% of the population in one city..  The problem I believe has been that a lot of industrial production has been dragged to Auckland because of haphazard Govt subsidies.   Would you expect tyre manufacturing in London, but a lot of low value employment is Auckland based.  The average household income is lower than Wellington (and I think Tauranga?).

I am aware of the argument that to be a competitive university (for instance) you need the scale to compete with staff and students with Sydney or Melbourne.   But I think the economic engine of Auckland is muddled and there is a lot of industry, transport etc that just doesn't belong there. 

 

 

Up
0

The agglomeration benefits of Auckland are very low compared to other major cities. And that is not because of under investment. Walking around the CBD last week for the first time this year I could see public money being spent on art galleries, theatres, recent road refurbishments, new Uni buildings, new underground railway, etc. I arrived by the taxpayer subsidized ferry (there were only two of us midday Friday).

To be fair the city centre has improved a little - for example the pedestrian area between Ferry, Britomart and Queen st. but the improvements of the last 20 years are undone by the number of beggars. My daughter used to live on Queen st but she has happily traded that convenience for work for a life in a North Shore suburb where people are not sleeping on the street and she feels safer despite her becoming another commuter.

Up
0

Competitive university needs a big city? Such as Harvard, Cambridge, Princeton? Auckland university should be closed down. AI is now replacing so many of the middle ranking bums-on-seats jobs that graduates used to fill. Rather than let all the NZ universities tighten their financial belts it would make sense to close one down completely, transferring academics to other universities. The obvious choice is the one that occupies the most valuable land and contributes to the most traffic congestion. Close Auckland Uni and those student apartments can be used to house the rough sleepers.

Up
0