sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Joseph Stiglitz points to evidence that the pandemic-era inflation was always going to be temporary and self-correcting

Economy / opinion
Joseph Stiglitz points to evidence that the pandemic-era inflation was always going to be temporary and self-correcting
Victory for Team Transitory

As the world was recovering from the pandemic, inflation shot up, owing to widespread disruptions to global supply chains and sudden changes in patterns of demand. While the demand shifts might have posed a challenge to price stability even in the best of times, the breakdown in supply chains made matters worse. The market could not respond immediately to the new demand patterns, so prices increased.

Recall that we initially experienced a car shortage, simply because there was a shortage of computer chips – a problem that took 18 months to correct. The issue was not that we had forgotten how to produce cars, or lacked trained workers and factories. We were just missing a key component. Once it was supplied, automobile inventories expanded, and prices came down – disinflation set in. (Disinflation is a decline in the rate of inflation, not necessarily of the actual price level, and is what matters for central banks monitoring changes in prices. In this and several other cases, prices actually came down.)

Housing provides another example of this temporary, self-correcting phenomenon. Since population size is a major determinant of demand, the loss of one million Americans under Donald Trump’s pandemic mismanagement ought to have lowered housing prices at the aggregate level. But the pandemic also induced people to look for greener pastures. Major cities like New York came to seem less attractive than places like Southampton and the Hudson Valley.

Increasing the supply of housing in such places is not easy in the short term, so prices duly rose. But owing to well-known asymmetries in how prices adjust to changing market conditions, they did not fall commensurately in the cities. As a result, housing-price indices (which capture the average) went up. Now, as the effects of the pandemic have waned, prices (as measured by these indices) have drifted down slowly, reflecting the fact that most leases last for at least a year.

What role did the US Federal Reserve play in all this? Given that its interest-rate hikes did not help resolve the chip shortages, it cannot take any credit for the disinflation in car prices. Worse, the rate hikes probably slowed the disinflation in housing prices. Not only do significantly higher rates inhibit construction; they also make mortgages more expensive, thus forcing more people to rent instead of buy. And if there are more people in the market for rentals, rental prices – a core component in the consumer price index – will increase.

The pandemic-induced inflation was exacerbated further by Russia’s invasion of Ukraine, which caused a spike in energy and food prices. But, again, it was clear that prices could not continue to rise at such a rate, and many of us predicted that there would be disinflation – or even deflation (a decline in prices) in the case of oil.

We were right. Inflation has indeed fallen dramatically in the United States and Europe. Even if it has not reached central bankers’ 2% target, it is lower than most expected (3.7% in the US, 2.9% in the eurozone, 3% in Germany, and 3.5% in Spain). Moreover, one must remember that the 2% target was pulled out of thin air. There is no evidence that countries with 2% inflation do better than those with 3% inflation; what matters is that inflation is under control. That is clearly the case today.

Of course, central bankers will pat themselves on the back. But they had little role in the recent disinflation. Raising interest rates did not address the problem we faced: supply-side and demand-shift inflation. If anything, disinflation has happened despite central banks’ actions, not because of them.

Markets largely understood this all along. That is why inflationary expectations remained tame. While some central-bank economists claim that this was due to their own forceful response, the data tell a different story. Inflation expectations were muted from early on, because markets understood that the supply-side disruptions were temporary. Only after central bankers repeated over and over their fears that inflation and inflationary expectations were setting in, and that this would necessitate a long slog entailing high interest rates and unemployment, did inflationary expectations rise. (But, even then, they barely budged, reaching 2.67% for the average of the next five years in April 2021, before falling back to 2.3% a year later back).

Before the latest conflict in the Middle East – which again raises the specter of higher oil prices – it was clear that a “victory” over inflation had been achieved without the large increase in unemployment that inflation hawks insisted would be necessary. Once again, the standard macroeconomic relationship between inflation and unemployment – expressed in the Phillips curve – was not borne out.

That “theory” has been an unreliable guide over much of the past quarter-century, and so it was again this time. Macroeconomic modeling may work well when relative prices are constant and major changes in the economy revolve around aggregate demand, but not when there are large sectoral changes and concomitant changes in relative prices.

When the post-pandemic inflation started more than two years ago, economists quickly divided into two camps: those who blamed excessive aggregate demand, which they attributed to large recovery packages; and those who argued that the disturbances were transitory and self-correcting. At the time, it was unclear how the pandemic would unfold. Confronted with a novel economic shock, no one could confidently predict just how long it would take for disinflationary forces to appear. Similarly, few anticipated markets’ lack of resilience, or how much temporary monopoly power supply-side disruptions would confer on select firms.

But over the ensuing two years, careful studies of the timing of price increases and the magnitude of aggregate-demand shifts relative to aggregate supply largely discredited the inflation hawks’ aggregate demand “story.” It simply did not account for what had happened. Whatever credibility that story had left, it has now been further eroded by disinflation.

Fortunately for the economy, team transitory was right. Let us hope the economics profession absorbs the right lessons.


*Joseph E. Stiglitz, a Nobel laureate in economics, is University Professor at Columbia University and a member of the Independent Commission for the Reform of International Corporate Taxation. Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2023, and published here with permission.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

38 Comments

I still think that electrification is going to continue pushing inflation.

Which might explain why some governments are starting to walk back on policies which support/are supported by electrification.

Up
2

Interesting theory.

If you're talking about electric vehicles (EVs) however, I think you'll be proved wrong.

Why? Because the cost to produce an E.V. is actually less than an ICE vehicle, as are ownership costs. So why are EVs so expensive? Number of reasons. Car companies have to recovery their development costs. Scarcity and demand pushing up prices (from those that can afford them). Pricing of them can be based on the economic advantage experienced by owners (e.g. much lower running costs), rather than production cost plus margins.

And if they get to actually produce batteries using some of the chemistry and battery tech being tested and trialed currently, prices for EVs will fall further.

Up
2

The batteries is what makes them expensive - currently around 35% of the vehicle price. And there's currently a price war going on that is on the verge of bankrupting dozens of manufacturers.

At the moment anyone buying one is effectively paying for about 10 years of running costs up front in the form of the increased unit cost.

Up
1

Your comment reflects "at the moment". My comment is looking 5 to 10 years out.

Up
0

Suggest you also have a close look at the domestic grid capacity

Up
7

With battery and solar prices dropping, you could incentivise a lot more home Solar + Battery installations and limit the increased demand on the grid?

Up
1

I have done. Numerous times.

I've also contributed to papers on solar, wind, wave and tidal energy production and the advantages of stored hydro and mass battery storage for leveling peaks. We've plenty of electricity generation potential. So much so that exporting it is a real possibility when the numbers stack up. That's what it comes down too ... "when the numbers stack up" ... That's why wind generation has exploded in Europe ... because the numbers stack up.

Up
0

I said domestic grid. Not generation.

Up
1

The same applies to Transpower's network.

Up
0

What's the landscape going to look like when we're at the point of exporting energy?

Will there be anywhere somebody could go and not see a dam, reflection from solar panels or looming wind turbines?

Up
0

We are already exporting it. For example, data centers (huge consumers of electrons) are springing up to service international markets. And that aluminum smelter just isn't dying.

You'll not see sub-surface tidal generation.

But I take your point. A long time ago when car manufacturers were killing off public transport I watched in dismay the increase (and dependence) on parking spaces and car parking buildings. People now accept the total waste of space dedicated to parking as completely normal and start bleating when they're moved.

Up
0

Your comment says EVs are cheaper to produce and it's just the development costs making them the price they are. That's simply not the case.

EVs are more a commodity (a battery in this instance) on wheels.

Up
1

Re-read what I said. Start with the bit that says "a number of reasons".

Up
0

Because the cost to produce an E.V. is actually less than an ICE vehicle

Your post is present tense.

Currently, it's more expensive to produce an EV. Otherwise the now 10+ year old Model S would be cheaper than a Camry.

Up
4

Re-read what I said.

Up
1

Not just transport.

But even so, it's the stranding of combustion driven machinery. Such things that have built up over time with population, but now with a large population there is potentially a huge wholesale shift. Which could be happening in a compressed timeframe = building demand for the same resources required for replacement.

It's the duplication as this transition happens. e.g. houses tied to the grid and having their own solar.

Up
0

My understanding is that people renting instead of buying does not meaningfully increase rental prices, because the number of rental properties available is also higher by one. Is there any good reason for Stiglitz to claim otherwise? 

Up
0

He explains that averages weren't affected that much but that averages don't reflect population drift from cities to suburbs, counties, states and to other countries.

Up
0

Sorry Joseph, little old NZ can't match the reductions in inflation seen in other countries because:

  • Higher interest rates have increased business costs by billions of dollars and businesses are passing that cost onto consumers. This is causing demand to drop, but businesses are just reducing supply to match.
  • High interest rates are putting pressure on a decent number of landlords who are hiking rents where they can to compensate. Thankfully, our Govt has helped them out by opening up on immigration so there is plenty of competition for over-priced weatherboard shacks
  • Most of our businesses don't really have to compete with many others, so prices here never really fall even when costs drop significantly. Hilariously our grocery stores offer 'the same fixed low price for a year' while the price of imported goods fall sharply. We fall for it because we have no real choice.
  • Our world leading unaffordable housing (rents and mortgages) mean that workers are pushing hard for wage rises so they can keep a roof over their head. This is adding cost to the private sector and more recently the public sector too.
  • We have removed the schemes we had in place to slow the pass through of higher costs to consumer prices - e.g. fuel excise cuts, public transport subsidies, and we didn't do the sensible stuff others have done (e.g. rent rise caps, intervention in grocery wholesale profiteering). Govt has left inflation-fighting to the central bank who are now busy crashing the economy and throwing tens of thousands of people out of work. It won't make any significant difference to prices of course, but hey ho, they feel important and it's doing a bit to keep the NZD from falling further.
  • We have underfunded infrastructure for years and ignored the threat of climate change and now we are getting found out. Local Govt rates and insurance costs are flying upwards and pushing real pressure on living costs.
Up
15

Can you think of another country with a similar OCR that is in a similar predicament to ours? Honest question

 

Up
0

Can you think of another country which had a government doing enough through covid and then had a central bank who thought it was a good idea to throw huge sums into the economy when supply disruptions were global?

No? Me neither.

Up
1

Standard and Poor's state,

"Many talk as if banks can "lend out" their reserves, raising concerns that massive excess reserves created by QE could fuel runaway credit creation and inflation in the future. But banks cannot lend their reserves directly to commercial borrowers, so this concern is misplaced".

https://www.hks.harvard.edu/sites/default/files/centers/mrcbg/programs/…

Up
1

RBNZ indirectly threw credit money into the economy by dropping interest rates and borrowing restrictions -  leading to a huge flow of commercial bank created money flowing into the economy. Whether that credit impulse had a major impact on prices outside of construction I am not sure.

What is absolutely true is that the Govt's fiscal response was sufficient on its own - we would have been far better off if RBNZ had basically shut up shop for a year or two. 

Up
9

Sweden and UK are pretty similar - very high private debt, mortgages that are relatively short-term, sensitive to imported price shocks, central bankers hiking like their careers depend on it, and Govts standing idly by and letting high prices flow through their economies.  

Up
1

So isn't UK inflation higher than ours?

Up
0

A bit, yes. 

Up
0

Are you disagreeing with him? I thought you'd be agreeing with him? I've always believed inflation would be transitory.

My view - and one that shouldn't be left unexamined - is:

a) the RBNZ actions through covid caused inflation to become rampant, and possibly entrenched (tho I strongly doubt it)
b) the RBNZ's actions now to reduce inflation are necessary (moot point) only to correct a problem they created!

So much of what we consume is imported so the falling imported cost can't be ignored for long (albeit it will mean inflation stays for longer until we realise we're being ripped off by NZ intermediaries). The on-shore drivers of inflation we can control. The problem, however, is that on-shore voting kiwis aren't that bright and too many are selfish, ignorant or shortsighted and want others (that typically can't afford to) to pay for it.

Up
3

No, not at all. The world is getting over with a supply shock inflation episode. My point I think is similar to yours, NZ has dealt with it badly because we treated it as demand-led and hiked rates to choke off that demand. We are now left in a position where high rates are putting net upwards pressure on prices - holding them up higher for longer than other countries. As a side note, I do think some of our price pressures were caused by excess demand (construction in late 2020/21 for example); but vast majority has been imported.

Really? Well, we import about $90 billion of stuff. Our total private + govt consumption is around $360m. So, imports are 25% of consumption. Now, if that $90 billion of stuff goes up in price by 28% in a year (and it did) it is not unreasonable to expect prices to go up by a quarter of that - 7%. Bill Phillips (of Phillips Curve fame) covered this in his 1958 paper - describing almost exactly what would happen in this scenario. Shame that the monetarists ignored that bit of the paper because it did not fit their priors.

Up
4

Ah. Thanks for the clarification. You OP makes sense in that context.

Now that's interesting. [Capt. Jack Sparrow voice.] We were discussing NZ's current recent position within the context of recent events and the Phillips Curve popped up. We had an adjournment while we consulted the textbooks to ensure we all had the same understanding of it.

(https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Phillips_curve)

Up
1

Here's the actual text from Phillips paper...

A third factor which may affect the rate of change of money wage rates is the rate of change of retail prices, operating through cost of living adjustments in wage rates. It will be argued here, however, that cost of living adjustments will have little or no effect on the rate of change of money wage rates except at times when retail prices are forced up by a very rapid rise in import prices... For suppose that productivity is increasing steadily at the rate of, say, 2 per cent. per annum and that aggregate demand is increasing similarly so that unemployment is remaining constant at, say, 2 per cent. Assume that with this level of unemployment and without any cost of living adjustments wage rates rise by, say, 3 per cent. per annum as the result of employers' competitive bidding for labour and that import prices and the prices of other factor services are also rising by 3 per cent. per annum. Then retail prices will be rising on average at the rate of about 1 per cent. per annum (the rate of change of factor costs minus the rate of change of productivity). Under these conditions the introduction of cost of living adjustments in wage rates will have no effect, for employers will merely be giving under the name of cost of living adjustments part of the wage increases which they would in any case have given as a result of their competitive bidding for labour.

Assuming that the value of imports is one fifth of national income, it is only at times when the annual rate of change of import prices exceeds the rate at which wage rates would rise as a result of competitive bidding by employers by more than five times the rate of increase of productivity that cost of living adjustments become an operative factor in increasing the rate of change of money wage rates. Thus in the example given above a rate of increase of import prices of more than 13 per cent. per annum would more than offset the effects of rising productivity so that retail prices would rise by more than 3 per cent. per annum. Cost of living adjustments would then lead to a greater increase in wage rates than would have occurred as a result of employers' demand for labour and this would cause a further increase in retail prices, the rapid rise in import prices thus initiating a wage-price spiral which would continue until the rate of increase of import prices dropped significantly below the critical value of about 13 per cent. per annum.

Up
2

What do you think the outcome for NZ will be then Jfoe? Imported inflation keeps dropping to below 2% which "makes up" for our domestic inflation remaining above 3? Seems to be what has happened over the last 20 years. (avg tradeable since 2000 = 1.4% and non-tradeable = 3.4%). RBNZ then pats themselves on the back and declares mission accomplished. 

What do you think of the RBNZ targeting getting Non-Tradeable inflation between 1-3% rather than the overall inflation rate?

Up
0

Yes, I think that is a very likely outcome - and is why RBNZ need to let non-tradable inflation float a bit more.

Our challenge is that we are going to need more real resources (people, materials, energy) to achieve the same standard of living. A road will cost more because it has to deal with climate extremes, insurance will cost more for the same reasons, Local Govt rates will be higher because our infrastructure needs major catch-up investment, higher safety standards mean more people required to do the same thing, house building will cost more if they have to meet efficiency and earthquake standards etc. Increased use of people, materials and energy means higher prices. But that's not really 'inflation'.      

Up
2

Ah but it is inflation… we don’t distinguish quality of the basket of goods… a 3brm home is still a 3brm home, doesn’t matter it has to have double glazing etc..

Also, these ‘staples’ feed into living cost pressures and cannot easily be substituted..

Up
0

Good stuff. Great even. Thanks Joseph.

Is anyone on the RBNZ's MPC listening tho ....

Up
0

How about doing the victory lap when inflation actually *is* back down?

Up
13

Inflation in the USA is back down. It is barely over 3% and still dropping. NZ is a bit different (probably due to issues that Jfoe has stated in another comment)

"Meanwhile all eyes on on the US October CPI data due out tomorrow. Expect a 3.3% rate" - from todays Breakfast Briefing

Up
3

I think this article misses the underlying inflation driver which is energy shortage driven by the war on fossil fuels.

Up
0

I have always said the Jacinda's excessive Covid and Immigration controls vastly affected supply of goods, and cost of goods by ridiculous red tape on all business.

Inflation has been running about 2% higher than it needed thanks to Govt Interference.

No workers to pick fruit just one of many thousands of examples that litter the countrside next to the corpses of businesses the Labour Govt has destroyed over the years.

Up
0