sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Brian Easton says the Government’s growth strategy seems to have little analytic content

Economy / opinion
Brian Easton says the Government’s growth strategy seems to have little analytic content
growth-strategyrf1.jpg
Source: 123rf.com

This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.


In 1990, the Prime Minister, Geoffrey Palmer, announced that he would halve unemployment – its rate was then more than 7 percent of the labour force. An OIA request turned up no technical papers. Apparently, the PM’s political advisers – jock wankers/politicos – thought the aspiration would go down well with the public.

More recently, the Minister of Workplace Relations, Brooke van Velden, presented a ‘Health and Safety Reform Construction announcement’ which proved to be, according to one exasperated journalist, ‘an announcement of an announcement you hope to make later in the year once you know what it is you’re announcing’. As the minister explained, her non-announcement (about the regulation of scaffolding) was ‘because people are really excited about this stuff. You should put it up on your website and see what response you get.’ Aspiration without content.

As Jonathan Milne in Newsroom newsletter commented:

Banning cellphones in schools when schools already had their own policies restricting cellphone use. Setting up a road cone tip line, inviting people to dob in excessive cone use. Banning gang patches. Banning voters from enrolling in the last 13 days before polling day. They're striking initiatives, guaranteed headlines and social media clicks. But what they have in common is the dearth of actual evidence behind them. They’re dreamed up in party-political strategy brainstorming sessions. There's little reference to the subject specialists in the public service; there's no prior consultation with the wider public and those who are affected.

An earlier, and perhaps more portentous, initiative was Christopher Luxon’s announcement that he was leading an ‘economic growth’ government.

Presumably he and his political advisers saw that the public thought the Luxon-led Government was drifting. (This is January 2025.) How could they seize the initiative? Economic growth was their suggestion, which Luxon adopted. But how to add content to the narrative? Cough, cough. ‘We’ll make Nicola Willis the minister for economic growth.’ As far as the politicos were concerned, the problem was solved. What was the analytic content?

Appointing Willis as Minister of Economic Development placed her in charge of the large amorphous department, Ministry of Business, Innovation and Employment, which had been created by Stephen Joyce in what was seen as a power grab. (It appears to have been partly to demote the previous minister, Melissa Lee, out of cabinet; I leave the politics to others.)

MBIE is really a ministry of miscellaneous economic affairs, with (over half the cabinet ministers holding or sharing its portfolios). It is not thought to function well and needs to get its various divisions to work better together. Handing it over to the Minister of Finance, who usually has enough on their plate, is odd. (Willis is also Minister of Social Investment.) In principle she is more powerful than Joyce ever was. I am surprised that there was no one else in cabinet to take the job.

Willis has not made much of a mark. She is in the public eye for trying to increase competition in the supermarket sector and reduce the price of butter, hardly matters central to the finance or development portfolios. David Cunliffe, when a junior minister in the Clark-Cullen Labour Government, was charged with increasing competition in the telecommunications industry (and got it right). Minister of Finance Michael Cullen told me he was right behind him, but the leg work was by the more junior minister. Willis is out front.

It is hard to see that the announcement has had much effect other than the ministerial reshuffle. The key ministers driving the government’s economic growth agenda are Chris Bishop, Shane Jones and David Seymour. The first two ministers are doing much as you would expect – improving infrastructure and exploiting resources. (Perhaps add Todd McLay, minister of trade negotiations, since thrust from the external sector is vital.)

Seymour’s involvement reflects a changing perception, here and overseas, of the determinants of economic growth. Economic theory has tended to downplay transaction costs – they are so difficult analytically. There are some Nobel laureates for transaction costs – notably Ronald Coase and Oliver Williamson – but there is little connecting their work to economic growth.

There has been recently an increasing focus on how transaction costs from public sector procedures are limiting economic growth. (Not a lot of attention is given to private sector transaction costs, which might suggest there is a whiff of neoliberal economics in the thinking.) There are a number of other ministers and ministries – over half a dozen on my count – who are also addressing regulatory standards. The most prominent, which does not mean the most effective, is Seymour’s Ministry of Regulation. In principle, its concern is improving the quality of public regulation. Sometimes the impression is that it is adding to the regulatory burden, as in the case of the Regulatory Standards Bill.

Of course, reducing the regulatory process may be a good thing if the resources it releases get usefully deployed elsewhere. But the gains are likely to be small in terms of GDP and not affect the growth rate. On the other hand, too little regulation can be a disaster. The reductions of building regulation led to the tragedy of leaky buildings, estimated to cost the housing sector alone between $11b and $33b plus a lot of heartache and some deaths.

I am not unsympathetic to the argument that some of our regulatory processes are unnecessarily burdensome and could be simplified. (I’ll address their impact on economic growth shortly.) But regulations serve other – often valid – purposes.

The most common justification is ‘market failure’ when unregulated market transactions damage GDP (as in the case of leaky buildings). Two others are often overlooked.

One is that where economic output is not the same as wellbeing, an intervention may shift economic activity towards higher wellbeing, albeit at the cost of depressing GDP. For instance, most healthcare interventions cannot be justified in terms of enhancing GDP but they add to longevity and the quality of life. Cut them back and since people will experience poorer health and die earlier, GDP per capita will go up.

Second, regulation usually has a distributional impact. In simple terms there are winners and losers. Changing regulation changes the balance between them. Abolishing them can abolish some people’s implicit property rights. For instance, some of the environmental regulations give the public, collectively, entitlements to environmental resources which they do not privately own. The effect of the Regulatory Standards Bill is to prioritise explicit private property rights over implicit ones. (The bill would be a better if it made this trade-off more explicit by requiring the reviewing process to identify them.)

I have long been looking at whether regulatory changes affect New Zealand’s economic growth rate. There have been constant promises to improve the growth rate, but there is not the slightest evidence that anyone has succeeded. (By ‘slightest’, I mean within the known margins of measurement error – say plus/minus 0.2 percent p.a.) I concluded that good economic policies keep the boat moving forward but no faster.

That was especially true with the major changes to regulation implemented by the Rogernomes. I had expected there would be gains and tried so hard to find them; I could find none. (I found some improvements in the ‘quality’ of output which are not incorporated in the measurement of GDP.)

Given the way the economy is tracking, I shan’t be surprised if per capita GDP is much the same at the time of the next election as it was when Luxon announced that economic growth was the government strategy (the level will be lower than it was in late 2022). Probably output will be moving up in late 2026 after stagnating this year. No doubt there will be confusion between a cyclical recovery and sustainable growth; a common mistake which politicians in charge like to encourage.

The Luxon-led Government's political advisers may well be looking for a new slogan. At the National Party conference, he announced that the New Zealand economy was ‘turning the corner’. One is reminded of Muldoon’s announcement of there being a ‘light at the end of the tunnel’. It proved to be a train coming the other way. We don’t know what is around the corner. 


*Brian Easton, an independent scholar, is an economist, social statistician, public policy analyst and historian. He was the Listener economic columnist from 1978 to 2014. This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

1 Comments

There are some Nobel laureates for transaction costs – notably Ronald Coase and Oliver Williamson – but there is little connecting their work to economic growth.

Touche.

'No doubt there will be confusion between a cyclical recovery and sustainable growth; a common mistake which politicians in charge like to encourage.'

There is no such thing as sustainable growth within a bounded system - and in that matter economists are as blind as any politician. And despite prodding, they seem to choose to remain blind. 

Up
0