sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

John Mauldin says taming inflation will be difficult, and the US Federal Reserve will have to clamp down even harder

Bonds / opinion
John Mauldin says taming inflation will be difficult, and the US Federal Reserve will have to clamp down even harder
jm

By John Mauldin*

This time last year, the great debate was whether inflation would be “transitory.” That question is now settled (Narrator: “It wasn’t transitory at all.”), we have moved on to debating what the Federal Reserve will do about it… and can do about it.

The experts at the Strategic Investment Conference fell into two camps: The Fed will move either a) too fast and spark a deep recession, or b) too slow and let inflation get much worse. (There’s a theoretical chance the Fed finds a perfect path in between, but I don’t know anyone who seriously expects it.) That means we are heading somewhere unpleasant; the only question is what kind of unpleasantry we’ll get.

My own opinion—admittedly in hindsight—is that inflation was already out of control before the debate even started. The Fed should have resumed “normal” policy in late 2020 or early in 2021 as vaccines eased COVID effects. They could have gone 25 points a meeting and backed off $10 billion of QE and normalized which would have given them some options. They didn’t and now have no options but to lean into inflation. Jerome Powell’s team kept emergency measures in place long after the emergency (at least the economic part of it) ended.

Powell knows recession is preferable to inflation (I’ll show why I believe this is true below), so I think he’s determined to err on the hawkish side—meaning a recession is coming soon. I’ve also wondered whether negative market reaction would sway him, as it did in 2018. Last week may have been a clue. An unexpectedly strong Consumer Price Index generated a major sell-off in stocks and crypto assets. Why? Investors seem to fear the Fed won’t do enough to rein in inflation. Then at this week’s FOMC meeting they decided to hike 75 basis points instead of the previously expected 50.

So, this was a twist. Powell gave the market what it wanted, but this time the market wanted tighter policy, not looser as it did in 2018. We’ll never know whether he would have bucked Wall Street because (for once) Wall Street demanded the right thing. He telegraphed the 75 basis point hike by a leak to Wall Street Journal reporter Nick Timiraos, who has evidently replaced John Hilsenrath as the new “Fed whisperer.”

While a few major banks called for the 75-basis-point hike the prior week, all the majors piled on following that report. The market priced in the full 75-basis-point hike almost immediately, giving Powell permission to do what he wanted to do anyway.

Unfortunately, I think everyone is too late. I believe significant inflation is probably locked in for the next year at least. It will come in waves of varying intensity, as happened in the 1970s, but the overall trend is set.

Today we’ll look at some evidence this period could even be worse than the 1970s. Then we’ll read the mea culpa regrets of someone who had a big part in that drama.

We need Volcker-plus

Throughout this period, we’ve seen a steady stream of 1970s comparisons. Usually they show today’s statistics, while bad, aren’t as bad as they were back then. Here is the year-over-year change in CPI since 1966. You can see from the red line that 2022 inflation is still far below that peak, at least officially.

That’s good news, but CPI doesn’t hit everyone equally. Here’s a chart we sent Over My Shoulder members last week, showing the average CPI change for four categories a typical household has little ability to control: utilities, gasoline, food at home, and electricity.

That red line shows today is uncomfortably close to late 1970s-level misery. And, as we’ll see below, there’s no reason to expect improvement anytime soon.

Larry Summers, one of the few prominent economists to see this inflation coming, recently co-authored a paper that finds today’s inflation is already closer to 1970s-level than most people think, if you make a proper apples-to-apples comparison. The difference lies mainly in the way CPI accounts for housing costs.

I have written many times about the 1983 introduction of “Owner’s Equivalent Rent” instead of actual home prices or mortgage payments. There were good reasons for that change, but it makes comparisons difficult for years before and after 1983. The index methodologies are significantly different.

Summers argues that the change means pre-1983 CPI figures, had they used OER to measure housing prices back then, would be lower than they now look. You can read the full paper for details, but here’s the key point.

“Our analysis reveals that current inflation, especially core inflation, is considerably closer to previous peaks than in the official series. Official core CPI inflation peaked at 13.6 percent in June 1980, whereas we estimate that core inflation was 9.1 percent in that same month when adjusting for the treatment of shelter inflation. Our estimates also suggest that the local trough of core CPI inflation in 1983 was considerably higher than originally reported.

“Overall, these estimates imply that the rate of core CPI disinflation caused by Volcker-era policies is significantly lower when measured using the current treatment of housing: only 5 percentage points of decline instead of 11 percentage points in the official CPI statistics. To return to 2 percent core CPI today, we thus need disinflation of a similar magnitude as Chairman Volcker achieved.”

That’s a lot to unpack with staggering implications if correct, which I think it is. It means Volcker’s aggressive rate hikes accomplished less than thought. That, in turn, implies today’s Fed will have to tighten even more than Volcker did to get the same effect on inflation.

Last month we sent Over My Shoulder members another paper on why the government took home prices out of its main inflation index. They made a similar calculation (which Summers cites as confirmation, by the way), finding CPI since 1983 would have averaged 2.2% without the OER change, instead of 2.7%. That small variance adds up when compounded over 39 years.

In this chart, you can think of the red line as what CPI would be without the OER change. It was both lower over the full period and quite a bit higher now. The chart ends at February 2022 and the subsequent difference seems likely even greater.

Today’s Fed is certainly not where Volcker was in policy terms. This week Powell turned slightly more hawkish. But come on—he is a long way from doling out the kind of harsh medicine Volcker did. Maybe he hopes it won’t be necessary. If so, we’d all better hope he is right.

Biting the bullet

Another parallel with the 1970s is the contribution energy prices make to inflation. And in both cases, a war served to trigger it. George Friedman had a reminder just last week. Going into October 1973, inflation was already a serious problem. Nixon had imposed a wage and price freeze and closed the gold window. Unemployment was rising rapidly. Then the other shoe fell.

“In October 1973, with Nixon wallowing in the Watergate scandal, Egypt and Syria caught Israel by surprise in a stunning and unexpected attack. The U.S. held back from supporting Israel, but as Israel started to run out of artillery shells and other necessities, the U.S. began to airlift supplies in. Arab oil producers responded by placing an oil embargo on the United States and Israel’s other supporters, particularly in Europe.

“It was a stunning blow to the U.S. economy, where oil prices not only rose but oil became unavailable. Gas stations that had fuel had lines of cars a half mile lined up. Oil was an essential commodity, and it was unavailable. Inflation surged. Unemployment soared as businesses closed. Interest rates rose as banks protected reserves. The oil embargo continued for months among some producers. It’s not excessive to say that the American and other economies were heading toward meltdown.”

This has some parallels with 2022. Energy prices and inflation were already rising before Russia attacked Ukraine. Like the Arab Israeli War, the Ukraine War intensified prior trends. There is a key difference, though. In 1973 the Arab countries refused to sell oil to the US and its allies. In 2022, the US and its allies, while not fully boycotting (yet), are trying to drastically reduce what they buy from Russia. But the result is the same: higher energy prices for consumers almost everywhere. This feeds through to other prices, raising inflation.

We are in somewhat better shape this time around because the US has much more domestic production capacity. We also have significant renewable energy sources. But relative to demand, they still aren’t enough, and we have few ways to quickly increase supply. This means any price relief will have to come from reduced demand.

The global supply situation is actually worse than you think. Non-US world production is 4.7 million barrels per day less than six years ago, and basically flat for the last 14 years. This means reduced prices anytime soon will require even more demand destruction.

Falling demand is not yet evident at airports or on the highways. The opposite seems more common: People are eager to travel after two years of COVID. This may change, though. Vacation and convention travel is typically planned well ahead of time. If fuel costs make the trip a little more expensive, most people will bite the bullet and go. But they may hesitate to plan the next one, meaning we could see a slowdown later.

The Federal Reserve would like to see that effect, and others like it, happen sooner. Its main weapon is to swing a large blunt object (higher interest rates) in all directions. This, the theory goes, will reduce liquidity and cause businesses and consumers to reduce demand for goods and services. Prices will then fall.

The theory works but not rapidly. Higher interest rates first affect the most highly leveraged sectors, two of which are stocks and housing. In stocks it is mostly indirect: Higher rates make fixed income assets relatively more attractive, reducing demand for stocks, whose prices then fall. This has a reverse “wealth effect” as stockholders see their net worth decline and become less likely to buy other things.

As for housing, higher mortgage rates are already pinching demand. John Burns’ team calculates that the increase since January from 3% to over 6% now means 18 million fewer households can qualify for a $400,000 mortgage. That’s a 36% reduction in potential demand.

Here again, this is what the Fed wants. They don’t have to kill the housing boom (nor should they) but letting some air out of the balloon will reduce demand for skilled construction labor, building materials, and the myriad things people buy when they move into a new house. That should help bring down CPI.

That balloon metaphor raises another question. Is it better to let the air out slowly, or just pop it? Paul Volcker pulled out the big needle.

Anguish all around: Against gradualism

Arthur Burns was Federal Reserve chair from 1970‒1978. He had previously been an academic economist and was an economic advisor to Richard Nixon, who then appointed him to the Fed. Inflation was already high when Burns took the chair and got considerably worse.

All that’s well known. What I didn’t know, until my friend Brent Donnelly told the story recently, is that Burns made a rather dramatic (at least looking at it now) mea culpa speech in September 1979. He had left the Fed 18 months earlier. His successor G. William Miller didn’t last long and Jimmy Carter had just replaced Miller with Paul Volcker.

Volcker wasted little time, further raising rates that were already in double-digit territory. Burns apparently wished he had done the same—and said as much in the speech. He seemed to agree central bankers hadn’t done their jobs.

“By training, if not also by temperament, they are inclined to lay great stress on price stability, and their abhorrence of inflation is continually reinforced by contacts with one another and with like­ minded members of the private financial community. And yet, despite their antipathy to inflation and the powerful weapons they could wield against it, central bankers have failed so utterly in this mission in recent years. In this paradox lies the anguish of central banking.”

At the same time, Burns also blamed the American public’s expectation the government would ensure prosperity and growth. He described it going back to the 1930s and then more in the 1960s. He discussed how this led to the inflation he had faced at the Fed.

“Many results of this interaction of government and citizen activism proved wholesome. Their cumulative effect, however, was to impart a strong inflationary bias to the American economy. The proliferation of government programs led to progressively higher tax burdens on both individuals and corporations. Even so, the willingness of government to levy taxes fell distinctly short of its propensity to spend. Since 1950 the federal budget has been in balance in only five years. Since 1970 a deficit has occurred in every year. Not only that, but the deficits have been mounting in size.

“Budget deficits have thus become a chronic condition of federal finance; they have been incurred when business conditions were poor and also when business was booming. But when the government runs a budget deficit, it pumps more money into the pocketbooks of people than it withdraws from their pocketbooks; the demand for goods and services therefore tends to increase all around. That is the way the inflation that has been raging since the mid-1960s first got started and later kept being nourished.”

He then seemed to offer Volcker some advice.

“Viewed in the abstract, the Federal Reserve System had the power to abort the inflation at its incipient stage fifteen years ago or at any later point, and it has the power to end it today. At any time within that period, it could have restricted the money supply and created sufficient strains in financial and industrial markets to terminate inflation with little delay. It did not do so because the Federal Reserve was itself caught up in the philosophic and political currents that were transforming American life and culture…

“My conclusion that it is illusory to expect central banks to put an end to the inflation that now afflicts the industrial democracies does not mean that central banks are incapable of stabilizing actions; it simply means that their practical capacity for curbing an inflation that is continually driven by political forces is very limited…

“The present widespread concern about inflation in the United States is an encouraging development, but no one can yet be sure how far it will go or how lasting it will prove. The changes that have thus far occurred in fiscal, monetary, and structural policies have been marginal adjustments.”

And here is the money shot:

“American policymakers tend to see merit in a gradualist approach because it promises a return to general price stability—perhaps with a delay of five or more years but without requiring significant sacrifices on the part of workers or their employers. But the very caution that leads politically to a policy of gradualism may well lead also to its premature suspension or abandonment in actual practice.

“Economic life is subject to all sorts of surprises and disturbances—business recessions, labor unrest, foreign troubles, monopolistic shocks, elections, and governmental upsets. One or another such development, especially a business recession, could readily overwhelm and topple a gradualist timetable for curbing inflation. That has happened in the past and it may happen again.”

You can read the entire speech but I think this is the critical part. We can’t know exactly why Burns said this. Maybe he thought Volcker was going to abandon gradualism anyway. Here’s a chart of the federal funds rate in Volcker’s first term.

Note those near-vertical lines. These 50‒75 basis point moves people now consider “aggressive” are mild in comparison. The Volcker Fed had multiple hikes of 100 bps or more. Volcker rewarded Jimmy Carter’s appointment by giving him an immediate recession going into 1980. Then they took fed funds 1,000 points higher in the second half of 1980, helping cost Carter the election and welcoming Ronald Reagan with an even deeper recession.

Volcker and his FOMC made no pretense of acting gradually. They did what they thought was necessary, generating enormous pain but finally stamping out inflation. I hope Jerome Powell will find his inner Volcker. This week’s 75-basis-point hike—widely portrayed as “aggressive”—was far short of the mark. Powell is practicing the very “gradualism” Arthur Burns did, and which he later admitted was a mistake.

This means, unfortunately, taming inflation will be difficult, and the Fed will have to clamp down even harder. Would we be better off with a Volcker-style rapid rise that kills demand across the economy? Or getting the recession gradually? I’m sure the Fed staff is telling the FOMC members they can get CPI and PCE back down without imposing such pain. I’m equally sure they have models showing this. We are going to find out if they’re right.


*This is an article from Mauldin Economics' Thoughts from the Frontline, John Mauldin's free weekly investment and economic newsletter. This article first appeared here and is used by interest.co.nz with permission.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

30 Comments

Apart from the COVID, the biggest difference between the US' situation in 2008 and now is that China did not buy in $780bn worth of US debt this time for obvious reasons.

Up
4

Central banks have to realise and admit that there is going to be pain either way, high inflation or recession and quite possibly both.  The sooner that CBs realise this, the sooner they can act and the better the outcome for everyone.  Expediency and speed is vital, unfortunately they are not words Central Banks are very familiar with.

Up
5

"Expediency and speed is vital, unfortunately they are not words Central Banks are very familiar with"

That depends.

In 2020....the expediency and speed that they dropped rates and pumped the QE was without comparison....

When perhaps they should have had a more watch and wait approach?

But then again, the central bankers had long positions in the markets then....

Now they don't....

Up
10

They realise it, The Markets are realising that they realise it.

The question is going forward if they want to limit oil use, and price inflation, how do they do this as the EV's are not there and neither is the infrastructure to charge them.....      I cannot see how they can limit cost of energy here....    i think inflation is now here big time.

Up
4

... the better the outcome for everyone ...

maybe they don’t want a better outcome. In order to ‘build back better’ all we have now needs to be pulled down, dismantled, destroyed. 

I don’t believe these things are random. They are deliberate acts by a coordinated group. We pay, we always have !

Up
4

Homer, my daughter is studying Determinism vs Free Will.   You clearly have a deterministic view, where you believe you have little choice or control over your won life. What if you believed a bit more in Free Will, i.e. you can influence and improve your own life?

Up
0

Au contraire, you are quite wrong. Personally, I’m in the free will camp. I’ve worked hard and built a family and businesses, successfully, by making good choices and being in charge of my own destiny. I’ve never shyed away from the hard decisions and have a healthy disrespect of those who wish to interfere and control our free will and God given rights.  Mother used to say that when you have self discipline, you need no other ! I guess I just lament that the tide is turning against us all to a greater or lesser degree and our autonomy to live our lives according to our own beliefs, is being eroded. There are huge forces at play !

Up
4

OK, good to hear and good on you, it was just your post that sounded a bit powerless

Up
0

Homer,

 "They are deliberate acts by a coordinated group". And just who are 'they'?  And since 'they' presumably prefer to act behind the scenes, how do you know who they are? 

Homer? More Simpson than Ancient Greek philosopher I think.

Up
0

To quote NHL 2002's colour commentary

"They're me Jim, every last one of them"

Up
0

Great picture - the look of a man who knows he's created the world a serious amount of pain...(through the excessively reckless actions taken to avoid any pain by printing magic money on a computer). 

Up
3

Oil is in short supply and the price is high, so we need to, errrrm, cause a recession to get demand below supply, and then the price will magically come down because the oil companies and OPEC will see the errors of their ways. This is next level stupidity. Interest should re-publish this article in the interest of some balance...

https://www.forbes.com/sites/johntharvey/2022/05/04/the-feds-interest-r…

   

Up
4

1000%. Gareth, special request? Or maybe another interview with Prof Keen? 😊

Up
0

Thanks for the link Jfoe, I have been interested by this view against interest rates increases and I have read the article in full.  There is one question asked in it (and not answered) which makes me dubious of its fundamental point, the question is:

Why are the rising prices and wages so catastrophic that we’d want to throw people out of work in order to “solve” it?

It seems to me that the answer is simply because prices = inflation, is rising at a faster pace than wages, hence the majority of people are actually getting poorer.  That's my understanding of why it's so important not to let inflation out of control.

Up
0

I think the point being made is that if a major input cost (oil) for many businesses is going up, then the price of the things that those business produce will go up. If this means that some people can no longer afford critical things (e.g. transport or heating), then lower wages have to increase.

In this scenario, price increases should have a redistributive effect - prices increase, so lower wages have to increase, but the pass through to higher wages is more muted. Ultimately, the higher price being paid for oil either falls back down because higher prices stimulate increases supply or the economy adjusts to the new, higher price level of oil.

Economists think that we will get wage / price spirals if we let wages adjust to higher prices. They tend to forget that wages are no longer index-linked and that the strong unions of the 70s have been destroyed. 

Up
2

Agreed. More fundamentally, what do interest rate hikes do supply shocks? Nothing. They are a complete non-sequitur. So, the hardship of price increases is compounded by the central bank-imposed misery of increased cost of credit for firms and consequent layoffs and unemployment. 

Up
1

Wait wait wait "hold off on $2 billion of QE"?  The Fed did less QE than NZ? Please tell me I misunderstood this.

Up
1

Where does the article say that? I see he talks about the Fed going 25 bp a meeting and backing off $10bn of QE, which I take to mean $10bn per meeting rather than they only did $10bn. I think the Fed's QE was measured in the trillions, they definitely did not do less than NZ.

Up
1

Per capita?

Up
0

You misunderstood this

Up
0

When the US starts cranking up its interest rates, NZ will have to follow suit or inflation will have rocket fuel sprayed on it. Imagine petrol/diesel around $5 per L, and transported food at twice its current prices.

Up
7

That ASB ad where the couple grows a ton of tomatoes at home isn't looking so silly now.

Up
1

New York fed sees "gradually worse" to look like this.

https://archive.ph/https://www.wsj.com/amp/articles/new-york-fed-model-…

(paywall removed)

I think that because we currently have much more money leveraged in the economy since the Volcker days, the OCR cannot be raised by a similar percentage. However, I agree that we have two options. Either inflation pain or recession pain... 

Up
1

Many here commenting has been saying it for ages and are not even experts or economist, so how could reserve bank goof up as they are suppose to be expert economist being paid royally.

Up
0

How is recession better than inflation?? Have they lost their mind, or do they want to deliberately impoverish everyone?

Up
2

It's not an either or. Inflation impoverishes.

Up
4

Not necessarily. Inflation of prices and wages makes zero difference to people without (net) financial assets. In fact, in many cases, people with debt will be better off in these circumstances. What definitely does impoverish the people who can't take any impoverishment is recession / unemployment.   

Up
1

Inflation reduces the purchase power of money owners. People who own a substantial amount of money or monetary assets represent a limited group within society, and purchase power reduction does not necessarily mean poverty. 

However, further rising interest rates will lead to a deflationary collapse of the entire system. This will indeed impoverish nearly everyone and make people dependent on intervention by the state. Perhaps that is the plan? 

Up
0

all of this has been caused by central banks stimulating demand in a supply shock. A perfect storm of lack of independent thinking and government in interference.

to get out of this the opposite is required. weed out Govt agendas and stimulate supply, i.e. declare pandemic over and pump more oil.

Up
1

Great post!

Up
0