sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Treasury has announced it's having a major review of its macroeconomic policy framework. Brian Easton sees 'old framework' approaches hampering that review

Public Policy / opinion
Treasury has announced it's having a major review of its macroeconomic policy framework. Brian Easton sees 'old framework' approaches hampering that review
broken fence
Image sourced from Shutterstock.com

No doubt there will eventually be a Treasury paper setting out their new macroeconomic policy position. Any change will reflect a shift currently going on internationally but it should be adapted for local conditions.

The statement is unlikely to state clearly the old policy framework. Yet there is a need to be reflective. Keynes said ‘Practical men [and women] ... are usually the slaves of some defunct economist.’ In practice the defunct theory will be overlaid with adaptations and fudges which have had to be made in the face of reality, but we carry its foundations deep in our thinking. It is evident, particularly, in much of the ‘expert’ comment which is quite unaware of its dependence on a failed theory. We cannot avoid that slavery without being explicit about the obsolete framework. So let me try to set it out.

In the late 1980s and early 1990s there was a revolution in our macroeconomic policy. The big change was the assumption that demand management – government spending, taxation and borrowing had little significant impact on the economy. It could not, for instance, change the level of unemployment much. That requires, it was said, supply-side measures like cutting the unemployment benefit, as happened in 1991, to give the unemployed a greater incentive to find a job. (The policy did not have much effect.) Wages had to be kept low relative to productivity in order to maximise jobs.

The framework assumed that short-term interventions did not work because the government was too clumsy. Interventions to smooth out the business cycle often reinforced the swings because they took so long to become effective. This was because the thinking was hugely influenced by American analysis based on the inertia in its government’s policy process. However our government arrangements are quite different and new policies can be quickly developed and implemented, as illustrated by the package at the beginning of the March-April 2020 lockdown.

Nor, said the framework, should we be concerned with the external deficit or overseas debt, providing the government was not borrowing overseas. Private debt was a private arrangement and of no concern to the government. What the analysis overlooked was that commercial bank offshore debt is different. As the Global Financial Crisis demonstrated, commercial banks can have recourse to the Reserve Bank, which means that the government may have to bail their foreign borrowing out. Today offshore commercial bank debt amounts to about 50% of annual GDP, up from about 10% in 1990.

The logic of the framework was that fiscal policy was neutered. Its predominant concern was the size of the government debt. The smaller the better. The result of this concern was a section in the Fiscal Responsibility Act (now incorporated in the Public Finance Act as Section 26g), which sets out a public debt management target. What it actually says is incomprehensible; I have seen a room of economists tying themselves in knots trying to work out its meaning; had lawyers been there too, the knot would have been truly Gordian. Ministers of Finance cut through by ignoring it.

Even so, the section gave the impression that the level of government debt was all that mattered for fiscal policy. You will recall Grant Robertson in opposition made a promise about low debts levels. Faced by the Covid Crisis, he claimed unusual circumstances (as Bill English had done in 2008).

Suppose the government had to bail out a vital New Zealand business – as Michael Cullen did with Air New Zealand and Trans Rail, following inept private sector management – or it built and owned state houses funded by borrowing. In each case there is a jump in the amount of government debt but it is offset by a jump in revenue-generating government assets. What matters is the quality of the overall government balance sheet, not some line in it.

Admittedly it is easier to stupidly focus on a single number. (When did you last see a serious discussion on balance sheet quality?) That does not mean we should ignore the amount of government debt – those lending to the government will not let it. But it is but one of a set of measures we should use to judge the fiscal position and it has to be evaluated in a total context including, especially, the offshore commercial bank debt.

The old framework, having written off the role of fiscal policy in managing the economy, gave the active macroeconomic role on the Reserve Bank and its management of monetary policy. Again this partly reflects American institutional arrangements for its equivalent (the Federal Reserve) has far more flexibility than the US Congress.

I agree that the Reserve Bank (RBNZ) should have operational independence on monetary policy. We don’t want a politician ringing the governor up directing what they should do. (Robert Muldoon used to.) But the rest of the monetary policy in the old framework only made sense if fiscal policy was impotent. I am not going to develop my analysis here which sees monetary policy by itself as relatively ineffective, taking a while to impact on the real economy (the impact on financial markets is faster). Instead I’m going to use the framework which the Treasury and many other economists use. Apologies for the simplifications.

The idea all those years ago was that the RBNZ set the interest rate to stabilise prices; that was all it could do. So the RBNZ was charged with maintaining a low inflation target. However in recent times the base interest rate has become so low that it is increasingly ineffective in the management of the economy. (In the jargon it is at or near the ‘zero lower bound’.) The analysis was first developed by Keynesians some ninety years ago with the conclusion that direct fiscal management was necessary.

Allow me to skip a discussion on a range of ‘unconventional’ monetary policies – such as ‘quantitative easing’ – which have been used since the GFC to deal with these very low interest rates. They were particularly necessary because fiscal policy was often ruled out (albeit not in every case). While they worked in the short term, there is much unease with the enormous liquidity that has been injected into the economy. The old framework says the measures are inflationary. While inflation has yet to occur, there is far too much liquidity swilling around and something disastrous is likely to occur in financial markets.

In any case, the Covid Crisis found monetary policy not very effective and almost every country added fiscal policy to cope with its economic consequences. (To be fair to the old framework, it was never designed to deal with a supply-side shock of this magnitude.)

So the New Zealand Treasury, and just about everyone else (I exclude much of our commentariat), is struggling with how to think through what next, but is hampered by the detritus of the defunct economics from thirty-odd years ago. I’ll try to keep you informed when (if) things become clearer.


Brian Easton, an independent scholar, is an economist, social statistician, public policy analyst and historian. He was the Listener economic columnist from 1978 to 2014. This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

9 Comments

It's easy to be clearer.

The measures we need to be adhering-to, are not monetary/fiscal; they are existential.

That means - perfectly clearly - that our accounting method has to be related to things physical (the reasons we're in the existential poo, is because they are not thus related).

Given that all life and all 'economic' activity requires energy, a good place to start might be by using it as a measurement. At the very least, a budget would have the potential to be guaranteed future-underwriteable physically.

Also sinks (physical capacity of the biosphere to absorb/nullify) need to be accounted, as - obviously - do the remaining resource stocks. Wealth, after all, is merely access to energy and resources. Logically then, wealth per-head increases as the population lessens; indeed keep the population above overshot levels (and we are orders of magnitude past that point) and there IS no wealth (we all become dead).

And 'the old regime was never designed to cope with a supply-shock' ? On a finite planet? What was it presuming, exponential physical growth forever? Hopefully no university discipline is ignorant enough to still be peddling such untruth......... Hopefully progeny of same ditto.....

 

Up
2

'enormous liquidity that has been injected into the economy'

Has it? Enormous amounts of potential liquidity have been made available to the banks but the only place it has been used is in the property market. If lending institutions choose not to lend then credit is not available to the wider economy. Banks in fact reduced the amounts of loans to business relative to property investment during the recent Covid period.

Now that the RBNZ and the govt has cracked down on the requirements for lending for property purchases,  that source of liquidity is drying up as well. Which means liquidity will re reduced not increased.

NZ gdp is down 3.7 percent for the quarter. For many  businesses liquidity is maintained by being conservative about new expansion plans going forward because of the unreliability of supply of materials and labour, the knowledge that banks are being conservative in their lending and the wholesale disruption of badly thought out new govt regulation at the local body level.

Govt fiscal measures went mostly to the wage subsidy to support workers. Business got very little support apart from this support. This was an liquidity injection that only partially filled a demand gap created by Covid.

$10 Billion that was usually spend overseas stayed  in New  Zealand. This was a source of liquidity.

The govt and the RBNZ made $60 Billion available as  liquidity to be injected into the economy but only $20 Billion was actually spent by govt or lent by the banks directly into the economy. So $40 Billion of potential 'printed money' never made it into the economy.

The conduit for increased liquidity was the housing market. Profits made on property sales were often recycled back into businesses and used to rebuild personal bank balances. If there hadn't been the property boom world wide New Zealand and the world would be in deep, deep, trouble.

If a govt is ideologically opposed to lending by govt agencies (which this one is except in dire emergencies) liquidity increases only when lending institutions allow it to. It doesn't matter how  much liquidity is sloshing around behind bank doors, if there aren't sufficient well heeled economic actors with collateral and good prospects that the banks are comfortable about lending to then the lending doesn't happen and the liquidity just isn't there.

 

Up
5

Government bonds are just central bank reserves that pay a higher rate of interest economist L.Randall Wray tells us here. https://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/Wray_Understanding_Modern.pdf

They both rank equally as a banks liquid assets the RBNZ tells us here. https://www.rbnz.govt.nz/-/media/ReserveBank/Files/regulation-and-super…

Banks don't lend out their reserves anyway, they create new money when they lend as the Bank of England tells us here. https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/quarterly-bulletin/2014/q1/money-creati…

Up
1

Print more money - houses go up

Print less money - houses go down

Which direction do you think monetary policy will go?

Up
2

It is truly mad that the discussion of Govt financial health focuses on an arbitrary number (net crown debt) that does not reflect the true health of the Govt balance sheet. It is like judging the wealth of a millionaire by looking only at their monthly credit card bill, or the balance in their current account.

Govt net financial position has been positive and on a steady upwards trend for the last decade due in the main to higher than expected tax revenues and increases in share values (driven ironically by Govt QE). The fact that Govt is not investing in the things that will make a real difference to the lives of millions of people (and future generations) is an absolute disgrace; the direct result of centrist politicians fencing themselves into a corner with ill-informed commitments to fiscal responsibility.

Up
4

It would be interesting to know what the banks do with all of this money that they supposedly borrow overseas because NZ Dollars are what we use in NZ and they can only be created in this country, either by the banks themselves as bank deposits when they lend or by the government as government currency when it spends.

Too much nonsense is spoken about government debt with very little understanding displayed by mainstream economists. Only MMT can give us a genuine explanation of what this borrowing represents and its purpose.

Up
1

"Where is fiscal and monetary policy going?"

By The Rich, To The Rich, For The Rich = Democracy

Up
2

Certainly is a massive failure. The appearance of prosperity has been achieved by saddling following generations with ever greater private debt - both financial and in natural resources - and we've pretended all is well. Living not off the fruits of productive work but off the wealth of the future pulled to the now. 

Up
1

The test for Treasury will be whether their assessment of economic policy has as one of its starting points the explicit recognition of what it means to be a sovereign currency issuing nation.

And the need for de-growth.

Up
0