sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Economist Brian Easton says the ongoing decline in market income inequality stopped in the 1980s. Since then it has been stable, while 1990 public policy actively increased disposable income inequality

Public Policy / opinion
Economist Brian Easton says the ongoing decline in market income inequality stopped in the 1980s. Since then it has been stable, while 1990 public policy actively increased disposable income inequality
Piketty

This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.


Thomas Piketty has a reputation for (literally and figuratively) weighty tomes. His 2013 best seller – 2.5 million copies – Le Capital au XXIe Siècle (Capital in the Twenty-First Century) was 696 pages. It was followed by a 2019 sequel, Capital and Ideology, of 1093 pages. It is claimed that the first is the most unreadable blockbuster on Google (second is Stephen Hawking’s A Short History of Time).

So it is with relief one turns to his 2021 A Brief History of Equality, with 274 (a fifth smaller) pages. It is consciously designed for the general reader; I found the translation more fluent.

The same themes are there: statistics and history show that economic inequality is widespread. One of the strengths is Piketty’s wider perspective from not being Anglo-American. The broad sweep of his account about France shows strong parallels with Britain and the US whose economic success was dependent upon imperialism and slavery. (Regrettably he does not pay enough attention to Germany.)

Piketty argues that the inequality is not an inherent feature of the market economy but is a political and social choice. He shows that in many Western countries inequality fell markedly between the late nineteenth century and about 1980. He advocates a more comprehensive welfare state.

Is that true for New Zealand? I summarised the available quality data in Chapter 50 of Not In Narrow Seas. Observe the ‘quality’; there is other data which a competent statistician would not trust.* Moreover, as the next few paragraphs illustrate, there are different measures of economic inequality and they do not always move in the same direction.

There is no New Zealand data I trust for the nineteenth century. If you want to believe that inequality was high then, so be it; I should not be surprised, providing you don’t think that the inequality was comparable to, say, Britain at that time.

The oldest almost-reliable data series is Census-reported individual incomes from the market, which begin in 1926. Despite scholarly caveats, it is possible to discern three periods. From 1926 to 1961, reported personal income inequality appears to have been broadly stable. From about 1961 to perhaps as late as 1991, inequality of personal income fell. A major factor in this decline was the rise of the income share of people in the bottom half of the distribution. By 1991, the decline had ceased and before-tax personal income inequality was roughly constant at about the level it had been in 1981.

Personal (before tax) incomes reported for income tax assessment can only be tracked back to 1937 before the personal series gets contaminated by business income. Because the IRD data is not granular enough it is only possible to follow top incomes. From 1937 the income share of those at the top 10 percent fell from about 35 percent to 25 percent in the 1980s. Since the 1980s the shares remain almost constant, although it seems that the share of the group just below the top 1 percent has increased, although not by much, perhaps because remuneration at the top of business and government agencies were rising faster than average wages and salaries.

Combining the two series, what seems to have been happening up to the 1980s is that inflation reduced the value of investment incomes and private pensions, while increases in paid labour-force participation meant a lot of women with low or zero income received big relative increases. Māori urbanisation would have had a similar effect. Unemployment was low.

The story of after-tax incomes is different. While market income shares remained much the same, the Inland Revenue data shows dramatic increases at the top after 1990. The top 1 percent of after-tax incomes leapt from 3.4 times the average after-tax income to 5.8 times.

This change was caused by major reductions in top income-tax rates at the end of the 1980s plus the introduction of tax imputation on dividends (in effect, corporation tax is now a withholding tax).

Combining this result with before-tax reported income, we can conclude that the increase in the after-tax share of those on top incomes came neither from working harder nor investing smarter. It came from the neoliberal tax breaks.

The disposable (after-tax and benefit) incomes of households are consistent with the personal income story. The effective income of the top 10 percent of households increased after 1990 by about the same 25 percent as the tax data shows. That means that those below – particularly the bottom 60 percent – had to take a hit. The biggest percent reductions were those at the bottom with their relative income share falling about 15 percent – not that they had much income anyway. (Children tend to be in the bottom.) Again we can conclude, broadly, that it was the neoliberal distributional policies which caused the increased inequality.

In summary

            – an ongoing decline in market income inequality stopped in the 1980s. Since then it has been stable.

            - since 1990 public policy actively increased disposable income inequality.

Piketty found a similar pattern for the affluent market economies he studied: falling market income inequality over a long period to the 1980s, a flattening out after. His argued the decline occurred when those who ran societies cared about having high inequality and took measures to reduce it. The measures included not just redistribution through taxes and transfers but ‘predistribution’, that is, managing the market economy to favour reduced inequality.

Among predistribution measures are:

            - prioritising low unemployment in economic management;

            - providing good quality ‘free’ public services, particularly healthcare and investing in skills of the young;

            - empowering workers, including high minimum wages, collective worker institutions and greater worker involvement in the management of the workplace;

            - pursuing a vigorous pro-competition policy, especially restraining monopolies.

Such a policy framework is an anathema to neoliberals and was abandoned when they came into power in the 1980s.

At the same time the distributional framework was undermined as the New Zealand-style generous welfare state (aiming to enable people to participate in and belong to their society) was replaced by an American-style minimalist one (with the lesser aim of enabling everyone to sustain life and health).

What is puzzling is that despite Labour having been in office for about half of the three decades since the end of the neoliberal changes, it has been timid in reversing their framework in favour of the traditional one of predistribution and redistribution. It has done some things but there is no obvious coherent vision. Explaining why is another column and a matter for public debate – unless one is committed to the neoliberal vision.

Piketty is not. He thinks inequality is a matter of public will, advocating predistribution and redistribution policies in each of his books.

* There is no long-run quality wealth series. I can immodestly claim that my 1956 and 1966 estimates of the wealth distribution are the best available before the official series which commenced in 2001. They are constructed using a quite different method and I am reluctant to make the comparison. This has not stopped others using unreliable data when it suits them.


*Brian Easton, an independent scholar, is an economist, social statistician, public policy analyst and historian. He was the Listener economic columnist from 1978 to 2014. This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

17 Comments

.

Up
0

Timothy Parrique is the more useful French go-to. Easton falls back into that comfortable anthropocentric mode; Parrique is a must-read if you're going to move your thinking on, Brian.

https://timotheeparrique.com/degrowthcontroversies/

https://open.spotify.com/episode/5jE92QKyMfzNpOHxidUaXJ

https://braveneweurope.com/timothee-parrique-degrowth-for-the-first-tim…

Homework time.

Up
1

In my humble opinion, Brian fails to consider the global economic setting and context in which the pre-1980s policies thrived. The pre1980s the "1st world" countries had the rest of the globe as their "captured" markets due to:

1) a massive capabilities gap between the 1st world and the rest in terms of know-how to manufacture and build modern things. 

2) a massive imbalance in political terms, where the rich countries were receiving the raw materials and commodities they needed for almost free from the 3rdworld countries. 

In NZ, having the UK as a captured market which enabled above normal returns for NZ agri products must have been THE driving force behind the country becoming wealthier as a whole. You can clearly see the decline in NZ economy starting with the loss of that market and the invention of synthetic wool. 

Thomas Piketty happily and totally ignores the massive increase in disposable incomes of Japanese, Chinese, Koreans, Indians, Vietnamies, Arabs etc since 1970s brought upon by the change in the global economic context. The fact the "global inequality" has reduced by all measures. 

Neo liberalism may be one of the worst ideas ever. But, do not forget that it got a chance because the absolute dead-end the previous setting reached by late 70s and early 80s. The pillars holding that system were eroded beyond repair and collapsed completely. 

Up
7

Brian's articles are always an interesting read.

I have never seen what amount of inequality is the right amount addressed.

Surly society requires an amount of inequality otherwise the outcome is sub optimum? 

Up
0

I do not think that it is the amount of "inequality" perse that matters. What is more important to consider is the context of inequality:

1) the quality of life for people at the bottom. If the poorest people of a society earn 50x less than its richest, yet what they earn is insufficient for the absolute basic needs they are far worse off than people in a society that the poor earn 150x less than it richest, but what they earn helps them to meet more of their basic needs. 

2) the prospect and hope of being able to affect your future, at least to an extent. I feel that we look at inequality when we feel the hope of the poor children to better their lives if they work hard is gone. In a way, having fluidity in moving between income deciles and the actual and perceived importance of meritocracy is more important than how much "inequality" are there in the system.  

Up
6

1) quality of life.  A recent graduate may have a massive debt but also have wonderous freedom and an enjoyable life.  The world still has 700m in dire poverty - Roslin's under $2 per day - they may have no debt but remain uncertain where their next meal will come from.

There is evidence that well-being & happiness roughly correlate with income up to $78k pa  - Is Bill Gates happier than me?

Up
1

2) It depends on the kudos you assign to wealth.  In the Scottish highlands when I grew up they gave most status to your relationship with God (fervent Protestants) so the crofter thought himself and his family the equal of the aristocrats.  Now the world worships money with only minor concern about its sources.

Up
3

I think that is true, it's more than money

Up
0

"Equality" is a difficult issue, and in my little mind, cuts into the fabric of our daily lives.

Up
0

I think Brian raises a good point when he mentions how labour governments over the past 3 decades have not pushed back against neo-liberalism via pre-distribution and re-distribution to those at the bottom of the income ladder. Certainly in my lifetime it was Labour who irst embraced the neo-liberal dogma and dismantled the support systems for those at the bottom of the food chain. Although it was National who in 1991 destroyed the Trade Unions with the ECA (Employment Contracts Act). Perhaps that thinking became entrenched in the hierarchy of the Labour party and continues to this day. Probably the party that comes closest to what labour originally stood for is the Greens.

Up
3

Brian did the "neoliberals" of the 1980's really abandon the policy positions you have outlined above

Competition to improve services was one of the drivers to get rid of some of the govt monopolies where services was frankly rubbish - think phones, ferries, rail, banking et al. Although we can argue how well this was achieved

Neoliberal drivers were also about better education (and health services) for all and also full employment - again we can debate the methodologies and how well we have progressed but I dont agree with the premise that the policy positions in NZ were bad for equality. 

There is also little evidence to support a better outcome from alternative labour party policies despite their time in charge over the last 30 years - In my view they have made inequality worse not better  

Up
3

Grattaway - re neoliberals privatising assets to get competition and improve services. How did that go? Rail - fell over with the collapse of the privatised owner (who ran the rail assets into the ground), and eventual buy back by the government. Telecommunications -  the privatised monopoly provider had to be subsequently broken up by the government. Banking - still very limited competition from the four large Aussie owned banks making monopoly profits off us kiwis. Electricity - while there are lots of power companies, we have had to endure poor network planning and overly high power prices.The over the top deregulation around housing construction led to the leaky housing scandal. The predatory pricing of our Supermarket duopoly has direct links to the laissez faire approach to regulation of markets. Government is now belatedly addressing some of the anti competitive behaviours by that duopoly.  The Commerce Commission is still in neo liberal fantasy land imho. 

Up
3

Piketty goes into quite a bit of detail on this but tl;dr the engine room of redistributive equality was the New Deal / Welfare State genesis post WW1 and Great Depression followed by the post WW2 consensus / Marshall plan

Basically massive Govt stimulus, well intentioned and well directed.

What has occurred since the 80s is effectively regulatory capture of both the left and right political classes, noting that in NZ, there's barely daylight between them as they both try to lavish goodies on the voting centre that swing elections (i.e. property owners and boomers).

Up
5

Yes to all of that. And you can add virtue-signalling in the form of wokeness, of recent times.

But the discussion if being framed in a bigger context; if you keep drawing-down the resources of a finite planet, even the elite are in the shyte at some point. And my point is that that point - is now.

Making this yesterdays' debate. We are now into a period of contention over 'what's left'; which isn't enough to get Russia/China/India up to US consumption-levels. Not to maintain US ones. Or ours. 

Summat's gotta give.

Up
4

Piketty's work has been thoroughly critiqued and debunked. Daron Acemoglu (Elizabeth and James Killian Professor of Economics at MIT) and James Robinson (Reverend Dr. Richard L. Pearson Professor of Global Conflict Studies and University Professor at the Harris School of Public Policy, University of Chicago), Lawrence Blume (Distinguished Arts and Sciences Professor of Economics and Professor of Information Science at Cornell University) and Steven Durlauf (currently Steans Professor in Educational Policy at the at the Harris School of Public Policy, University of Chicago, previously the William F Vilas Research Professor and Kenneth J. Arrow Professor of Economics at the University of Wisconsin-Madison), Lawrence Summers (71st US Secretary of Treasury, previously 8th Director of the National Economic Council and currently Professor and Director of the Mossavar-Rahmani Center for Business and Government at Harvard Kennedy School), Jason Furman (Aetna Professor of the Practice of Economic Policy Harvard Kennedy School) and Peter Orszag (previously 37th Director of the Office of Management and Budget under Obama, currently CEO of Financial Advisory at Lazard).

The list is way, way longer of people who have written fairly detailed, at best, criticism of Piketty, at worst, completely debunking him.

Up
1

To compound the confusion the NZ we have today is very different from that of 1990, demographics have changed markedly. Could we expect the same productivity that was displayed in that era? 

Up
0

We can measure inequality in attitudes as well as in money. Some people just don't wont to work. That's their choice. For them there is welfare (& plenty of it too). For others who do wish to work, the world is their oyster. They are still crying out for good workers of all descriptions, skill-sets, colours & cultures. If you work, you're going to do alright. If you work really hard, you might even do really well. If you are born with a silver spoon in your mouth then you could do amazingly well, although many in this category don't really appreciate what they have got & many will blow the opportunity they have.

For most of us, including me, I had to work really hard to become moderately wealthy (comparatively speaking) in NZ. That still puts me in the top 10% of the planets population which I also understand having travelled a lot when younger. Many people in NZ do not understand how wealthy they really are, globally speaking. This is a shame. For even those with nothing in New Zealand have something, once again, globally speaking. It's quite a sad fact, that they will never really understand that.

Up
0