sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

New research for the Reserve Bank says if central banks had mandates to prevent unsustainably high house prices they would likely find interest rate changes more effective than macroprudential tools, such as LVR limits, to achieve this goal

Personal Finance / news
New research for the Reserve Bank says if central banks had mandates to prevent unsustainably high house prices they would likely find interest rate changes more effective than macroprudential tools, such as LVR limits, to achieve this goal
house-glassrf1.jpg
Source: 123rf.com. Copyright: victorhenry

Central banks "could be justified" in using interest rate rises to combat high house prices, new Reserve Bank research has found.

A comprehensive discussion paper by Reserve Bank economist Andrew Coleman has examined the reason why housing markets have such unusual price and building activity cycles.

It follows on from a suite of research issued by the RBNZ last year, which followed the inclusion in 2021 and 2022 of housing in the RBNZ Monetary Policy and Financial Policy Remits.

In a wide-ranging paper, Coleman discusses "cyclical backwardation", which occurs when current house prices (or rents) are temporarily above the usual cost of building homes and developing land, and are expected to fall back to usual levels in the future and "structural backwardation", which occurs when current prices (or rents) are at usual levels, but the normal costs of building homes or developing land are expected to fall permanently. Property prices can be said to be “cyclically backward” or cyclically unsustainable when capacity constraints in the property construction and development industry lead to temporarily high house prices and temporarily high construction costs, Coleman says.

He says one conclusion seems clear.

"If a central bank wants to reduce the extent that property prices are cyclically backward, it could do so by raising interest rates. There is little reason to doubt that a period of temporarily higher interest rates would reduce the demand for better quality property, and thus reduce the extent that property prices are unsustainably high," Coleman says.

"There are some reasons to believe that central banks could be justified in choosing interest rate paths that reduce cyclical house price backwardation. House price expectations have an important role in determining actual house prices, and there is considerable evidence that these expectations depend on recent house price movements. When this occurs, house prices can be subject to periods of substantial under-or over-valuation, movements that have significant effects on construction activity. In these circumstances, decisions to use higher interest rates rather than higher prices during periods of cyclical backwardation may be warranted."

Coleman notes that most central banks do not have a mandate to prevent unsustainable house prices. Rather, they have a mandate to achieve general price stability, maximum sustainable employment and financial stability.

"During the last decade there has been extensive research examining the relative merits of using interest rate changes rather than macroprudential regulations and interventions (such as loan-to-value restrictions or capital-lending balance-sheet ratios) to prevent financial crises or episodes of financial instability.

"While these issues are far from settled, most central banks including the Reserve Bank of New Zealand favour the use of macroprudential interventions to prevent financial instability rather than as a means to directly target economic outcomes. This is one reason why central banks have not attempted to raise interest rates to prevent rapid increases in house prices in recent years.

"Nonetheless, the literature consistently suggests that macroprudential interventions have relatively minor effects on house prices. Consequently, if central banks had mandates to prevent episodes of unsustainably high house prices, they are likely to find interest rate changes to be more effective than macroprudential interventions to achieve this goal."

Population growth & demand for better houses drivers of new construction

Coleman says both population change and an increased demand for better quality houses have been "an important driver" of new construction in New Zealand over the last three decades, "and they are likely to be jointly responsible for the pressures that have caused cyclical price backwardation".

"Between 2000 and 2020 the population increased by 1,225,000 people, or by 1.4% per year, twice the average rate in the OECD.

"Given an average occupancy rate of 2.75 people per household, this population increase implies the need for an additional 450,000 houses.

"At the same time, estimates linking the change in building activity to population change suggest there is a 'background' construction rate of 30 houses per 10000 people even when there is no population growth, to replace dilapidated houses or to change the housing stock as the demographic structure and tastes change.

"This implies demand for a further 250,000 houses over the period. In combination, these numbers indicate that between 30% and 40% of the potential demand for new houses was for quality improvement over the two decades," Coleman says.

"Only 510,000 new dwellings were consented over the period, however, suggesting there was a large shortfall in new construction.

"These numbers further suggest that improvements in quality may have accounted for half of the new building that actually occurred between 2000 and 2020, particularly since builders tend to construct high quality houses before low quality houses as they are more profitable. The demand for higher quality properties has most likely stemmed from changes in income, interest rates, and the tax regime."

Coleman says there is very little formal analysis of the extent that "episodes of cyclical house price backwardation" redistribute income or wealth or cause welfare losses.

"Without such analysis it is not clear how to evaluate the costs or benefits of strategies that reduce cyclical backwardation."

He says given the inclusion of housing into the RBNZ's Monetary Policy remit, "it is perhaps time that this analytical work was undertaken".

Areas for further work

Coleman says there are three areas for further research work that stand out.

First, there is limited literature examining how quality improvements are related to fundamental supply and demand factors, including interest rate changes.

"This area is difficult, as the flow of quality improvements is related to differences in the current and desired quality profile of the whole stock of houses. Little is known about the relative demand elasticities for bigger houses rather than better located property, for example."

Secondly, little is known about the welfare consequences of price backwardation, especially price backwardation that is associated with construction-sector capacity constraints.

"There are many aspects of this question to understand. Some are technical. For example, is the rationing that occurs when the construction sector reaches a capacity constraint efficient? In reality, does the construction sector disproportionately build higher quality houses because they are the most profitable to build? Are there adverse welfare consequences arising from the tendency of the construction sector to build the most profitable, highest quality houses? Other questions concern the appropriate metrics that should be used to evaluate welfare, including the appropriate time horizons and the way to consider the welfare of different generations."

Thirdly, the appropriate monetary policy response to price backwardation is not well understood.

"It depends on the welfare costs of price backwardation, if any; it depends on the importance of these welfare costs to the central bank, if any; it depends on the tools available to the central bank to respond to these episodes; and it depends on the relative costs of these interventions relative to other interventions.

"This is a long list of topics for future research, suggesting there is a lot of work to be done," Coleman says.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

28 Comments

Yes all that dropping interest rates to zero achieved, while importing deflationary pressures from globalisation over the past 30 years, was create major asset bubbles in the share, bond and property markets of anglosphere nations around the world. (i.e. we used the cheap labour of Asian countries to bolster our own quality of living - and believed we were getting wealthier - in reality we were getting poor as we loaded up with more debt and less productivity). 

Asset price = cash flow / discount rate is the key equation to understand.

All we've done is make the denominator smaller and the resulting asset price has gone up! Now that we make the denominator bigger then the reserve occurs to asset prices. 

This policy used by central banks, will quite likely in hindsight, look very foolish. Especially given that land/residential housing isn't part of the CPI measure. 

Up
14

The last point you make (land/housing not in CPI measure) is the most valid one surely. So

- Central banks need less KPIs not more. Th emore KPIs the harder it is to hit any of them and there is potential for conflict between KPIs. Inflation target should be their primary remit - the rest should be managed by government. Overseas CGT and similar are the tools used to control house pricing. 

- Why on earth land/residential housing isnt in the CPI measure is the crux of the issue. everything should be included in CPI. then there is no need to create separate kpi for housing.

 

Up
4

My argument on here for many years that it is impossible for residential housing to substantially grow faster than wage inflation over the long term - and the only reason it has happened in recent decades is because mortgage rates have gone from 20% to 0%.

A large number, like the average house prices at $1,000,000 NZD cannot grow at 7% continuously (ie double every 10 years...), when it is funded by wages (average household income around 1/10th of that) that have been growing at 2-3%. The cash flows don't add up...if you understand P = CF/discount rate you know how mad the last 40 years have been. Reducing interest rates has pumped asset prices at a rate that is highly unsustainable - especially housing in anglosphere nations. 

Before the 1980's (approx), house prices were flat in real terms (i.e. the grew around the rate of general inflation) because they only grew at the rate that wages would allow. Dropping interest rates for 40 years has allowed house prices to grow much faster than wages - but that is completely unsustainable! And if we have flat/rising interest rates for a period, then this is going to become very clear to everyone. 

Up
13

I guess the other part of the equation is restrictive zoning laws that have made it increasingly difficult and costly to build which has artificially restricted the quantity of housing we were able to produce.

But ultimatly like you said people can only afford so much on their incomes so artifically restricting supply can only get you so far in upping house prices until something breaks. 

Up
5

+ the emergence of the dual-income household; another one-off change that will never be repeated. 

The 'NZ house prices double every 7-10 years' gospel is simply moronic recency bias at the population level. 

Up
10

Wonder what happens long term if the global population starts shrinking rather than growing which has been the trend in industrialized nations lately.

Up
3

You'll just get multi-gen families living and buying together = 4 income household. 

Up
0

Remove the employment mandate for RBNZ and they can get back to doing what they are supposed to. They can't get max employment and reduce inflation so are set up to fail. 

Up
3

Asset price = cash flow / discount rate is the key equation to understand.

This stopped being the logic used ages ago but is how value used to be and should be assessed. If this logical process starts to reapply, then those leveraged speculating on capital growth are in for a bath.

Up
1

Cash flows will need to rise enormously if they are to maintain current prices (because small changes in the denominator result in large changes in the asset price) - but the problem with that if we have large increases in the cash flows, then it means we have significantly higher inflation, which will cause central bankers to raise rates even higher. Which means that the denominator gets even bigger and the asset prices fall even further.

Up
1

Still stand by this - from 2021

 

by Independent_Observer | 25th Sep 21, 11:25am

Also - very soon - there are going to be a lot of mortgage free retired boomers and young people locked out of the housing market, who will want interest rates to rise. Boomers because they want return on their savings, and young people because they also want return on their savings for a house, and because of the destructive impact it will have on real house prices (perhaps not nominal, but real).

So suddenly there could be significant political pressure to reverse the policies for the last 40 years, where boomers, the largest demographic, have wanted falling interest rates so they can exploit everything for their own best interests - pretending that its all about 'inflation targeting' (when clearly it is not based upon recent central bank behaviours) - will be cheering on central banks to raise rates and pushing pressure on governments to do so.

 

by Roger the dodger | 25th Sep 21, 1:06pm

The mean age of the baby boomer generation is already over 65.

Many will be sadly deceased and of course you will happily tell us that all of the rest have made a fortune on real estate.

So why would they wait to retire at 65?

If your hypothesis has any merit then it will be observable right now.

 

by Independent_Observer | 25th Sep 21, 1:23pm

Many have made a fortune from real estate 'on paper'. But most are asset rich and cash poor.

The average NZ home, at nearly a million dollars, is worthless if you can't afford to pay your rates or power bill based upon superannuation payments or interest on whatever savings they have.

If inflation is really here, which it appears to be, and the reserve bank want to pretend its not, its going to be eroding away at the quality of the boomers retirement lifestyle. That won't sit well with them at all.

The longer the central banks keep the OCR below the actual level of rises in the costs of living that people are experiencing on a daily basis, we are all becoming poorer.

This will take a few years to play out of course as people start to figure out what is going on - right now people are focused on COVID and can't see the forest for the trees. But the past 40 years its been in boomers interests for rates to fall so they can clear their mortgages - that has changed now. Its now in their interests for rates to rise.

Up
11

by Audaxes | 5th Jan 22, 8:56pm

..it can be plainly seen today that the most important macroeconomic variable cannot be the price of money. Instead, it is its quantity. Is the quantity of money rationed by the demand or supply side? Asked differently, what is larger – the demand for money or its supply? Since money – and this includes bank money – is so useful, there is always some demand for it by someone. As a result, the short side is always the supply of money and credit. Banks ration credit even at the best of times in order to ensure that borrowers with sensible investment projects stay among the loan applicants – if rates are raised to equilibrate demand and supply, the resulting interest rate would be so high that only speculative projects would remain and banks’ loan portfolios would be too risky. - Link - section II-3

Up
1

Banks have migrated away from lending to productive business enterprises because the risk weights can be as high as 150%. Thus around 60% of NZ bank lending is dedicated to residential property mortgages owed by one third of already wealthy households

Up
8

The above posts go completely over most people's heads Audaxes - but completely agree. 

As Henry Ford once said:

It is well enough that people of the nation do not understand our banking and monetary system, for if they did, I believe there would be a revolution before tomorrow morning.

Interesting he made this observation during the 1920's during a boom similar to what we have just experienced - and just before the financial system caused global suffering in the form of the 1929 share market crash and great depression. 

Up
6

indeed, in the absence of investment in productivity improvements, our economy has to rely instead on banks pumping in ever more newly created credit money, which, at ever lower borrowing rates, enables people to bid up the price of our weatherboard palaces and create the classic ponzi. When we reach peak stupid, the credit flow dries up and our economy falls on its arse. This is the phase of the cycle we have been in for the last 12 months - with the impacts on spending, unemployment etc coming through now (with the usual 12 months lag).     

Up
6

Ahhhh duhhhhhhh!!! Why didnt they do this 5 years ago when house prices were going out of control? 

Up
3

They needed more time to produce word salad buffet.

Up
2

Stay tuned folks - next RBNZ will be announcing that moving short-term interest rates up and down is the very bestest way to tackle productivity, stop ram raids, improve water quality, and end the war in Ukraine.

The idea that you would use a blunt instrument like interest rates to intervene in a specific asset market (housing) is really, really dumb. The collateral damage is huge. 

Up
2

Suggesting a mandate is required for sustainable house prices ignores that there is already a mandate for financial stability. Is it not obvious that house and asset prices in combination with credit creation are a direct cause of financial instability?

Great comments above IO... one has to really ponder our economic theory and beliefs... The last 40 years almost appears to be by design by the financial industry... Literally debt servitude for the masses.

Policymakers are between a rock and a hard place though... The conflict between the goals of capitalism and financial stability/economic and social wellbeing could be too great... The solution is ultimately a paradigm change in beliefs... The belief in ever increasing asset prices as the means to "wealth" may be inherently flawed...

Up
3

And not a mention of the wisdom of inflating our popn so we that need to build more and more and more and more and more and ....

Id like t ask these clowns...just when does the more and more  actually STOP. 

 

 

Up
5

Inflating the population, you mean by the advances in medicine and science that allows people to live so much longer?

After all the population pyramid is inverted and we have a lot less young people to elderly than we used to have. 880k on the elderly benefit

Up
0

As frank likes to tell you, we used to make stuff in this country. Build stuff.

Now we just stick our hand in the next guys pocket. 
 

 

Up
4

That's the problem when your tax and financial systems make "taking" behaviours (rent seeking, speculation, excess bureaucracy) more rewarding than "making" behaviours (physically building or growing stuff, performing essential services). Eventually you end up with everyone trying to be a "taker" and a dwindling pool of "makers" from whom to take. Economic growth slows, inequality and class division soar.

Young people see their path to success as being governed by speculation, lucky timing and inheritance. Hard work is almost an incidental factor in the equation and many will only work hard enough to sustain their current lifestyle, with little thought for the future. 

Not just an NZ problem, virtually the whole Western world is on the same path to misery. 

Up
7

Agreed. The myth of the hardworking boomer followed by feckless youth has been well and truly popped this past year

Up
4

Gee, how surprising.

Houses are only the biggest consumer item. Of course the CPI should fully reflect house prices.

By not including them let’s interest rates drop too low like they did and now we are chasing a fancifully high CPI as house prices drop.  

The swing in interest rates without full house prices is exaggerated which further exaggerates the house price swings which are proportional to x/interest rate.

it’s not the only factor though - high immigration, tight land use rules. oligopoly building supplies, money laundering and no capital gains/wealth tax makes it even worse.

Up
4

I like the thrust of this thinking. Hope something comes of all the research where they gather house price controls into their remit to smooth out the boom/bust cycles. Macro prudential policies have demonstrably failed. Especially in terms of the welfare aspect of building programmes where a stated builders go for constructing higher quality houses to maximise profitability. Not sure how they might influence building welfare housing though. The government should be all over building welfare housing.

Up
1

This report raises one question that I think may have been very consequential - how much of the capacity problem in construction is because it’s more lucrative to do renovations than new builds (and homeowners can borrow money for reno more easily because they have equity). I’ve lived in the inner suburbs of Auckland for the last ten years, and every street has had several year-plus renovations going on at any given time. Often the work is inessential- landscaping, luxury garages, bespoke pizza ovens and the rest. If that labour had been directed towards new housing things might be quite different now.

Up
1

yep, and the exceptional impact of over-regulation in housing...sure double glazing's great and cladding cavities help, but the absurd costs added to a basic house means people are sleeping in cars, vans, pods and motels. I counted 8 sleeping places(vans pods caravans) on one local section AND the 3br ex-state house. Add the bank regs requiring FHBs to have cash to complete all renos and the do-er uppers are also out of reach. Like Winston Churchill said , if you have 10,000 regulations you destroy all respect for the law...

Up
2